全文获取类型
收费全文 | 40321篇 |
免费 | 768篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 7513篇 |
工业经济 | 3110篇 |
计划管理 | 6685篇 |
经济学 | 8959篇 |
综合类 | 463篇 |
运输经济 | 245篇 |
旅游经济 | 634篇 |
贸易经济 | 6204篇 |
农业经济 | 2024篇 |
经济概况 | 5169篇 |
信息产业经济 | 2篇 |
邮电经济 | 81篇 |
出版年
2021年 | 229篇 |
2020年 | 387篇 |
2019年 | 515篇 |
2018年 | 725篇 |
2017年 | 706篇 |
2016年 | 673篇 |
2015年 | 496篇 |
2014年 | 740篇 |
2013年 | 3907篇 |
2012年 | 1034篇 |
2011年 | 1133篇 |
2010年 | 938篇 |
2009年 | 1126篇 |
2008年 | 1146篇 |
2007年 | 1005篇 |
2006年 | 947篇 |
2005年 | 930篇 |
2004年 | 873篇 |
2003年 | 900篇 |
2002年 | 796篇 |
2001年 | 816篇 |
2000年 | 810篇 |
1999年 | 733篇 |
1998年 | 732篇 |
1997年 | 713篇 |
1996年 | 728篇 |
1995年 | 667篇 |
1994年 | 707篇 |
1993年 | 673篇 |
1992年 | 668篇 |
1991年 | 698篇 |
1990年 | 629篇 |
1989年 | 519篇 |
1988年 | 537篇 |
1987年 | 500篇 |
1986年 | 557篇 |
1985年 | 803篇 |
1984年 | 762篇 |
1983年 | 744篇 |
1982年 | 710篇 |
1981年 | 652篇 |
1980年 | 607篇 |
1979年 | 633篇 |
1978年 | 543篇 |
1977年 | 474篇 |
1976年 | 388篇 |
1975年 | 377篇 |
1974年 | 360篇 |
1973年 | 316篇 |
1972年 | 281篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
11.
Poverty Traps and Index-Based Risk Transfer Products 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
12.
Using a sample of Australian Multi-sector trusts we examine selectivity and market timing performance and extend the analysis to include the relatively new measure of volatility timing. This is of particular relevance to our data set, as high levels of volatility persistence are prevalent in Australia. In addition we consider the stability, asymmetry and seasonality of the various performance and risk measures. A survivorship adjustment procedure is also employed in order to assess the impact of survivorship on selectivity, market timing and volatility timing performance. 相似文献
13.
The purpose of this paper is to analyze the impact of the Bank of Japan's official interventions on the JPY/USD parity during the period 1992–2004. The novelty of our approach is to combine two recent advances of the empirical literature on foreign exchange interventions: (i) drawing on over-the-counter option prices to characterize more precisely the distribution of market expectations; (ii) redefining interventions in terms of events as they tend to come in clusters. Moreover, in order to deal with the features of the data (small sample size, non-standard distribution), we use bootstrap tests.We show that interventions have a significant impact on the mean expectation (the forward rate). The results are more ambiguous for variance. Additionally, we find that the effect of interventions on skewness is significant, robust to different definitions of skewness, and consistent with the direction of interventions. On the contrary, our results clearly show that kurtosis is not affected by interventions. We finally show that: (i) coordination increases effectiveness of interventions; (ii) results are not altered when controlling for other economic and political news. 相似文献
14.
This paper develops and estimates models of family and sex-specific emigration, as well as the sex composition of this emigration, from 12 European source countries to the U.S. for the period 1870–1910. The models are based on the distinction between economic migrants (males, single females, and some married females) and tied or trailing migrants (females) and are estimated with panel data, including data that relate to the occupational/industrial structure of male and female economic activity in source countries. Hausman-Taylor instrumental variable estimates suggest that although both males and females responded to labor-market signals, males were more responsive than females to per capita GDP differences. Moreover, compared to the rest of Europe, Ireland, and Scandinavia were the sources of many young, single male, and female migrants, who responded strongly to gaps in economic opportunities. In fact, much of the European response to such gaps appears to be due to migrants from Ireland and Scandinavia. Females tended to originate in English-speaking countries and countries that were agriculturally oriented. Service and manufacturing jobs in source countries discouraged the migration of females relative to males. Males tended to follow recent migrants more than females, but females responded more to long-term influences as measured by stocks of migrants from their source countries who had previously settled in the U.S. Countries with high birth rates had relatively fewer female emigrants, whereas those with high rates of natural increase 20 years earlier experienced relatively more male emigration. Intact families, other family members (including family-strategy male migrants and trailing female migrants), and single males and females responded strongly to economic incentives, but the singles were most responsive followed by family-strategy males. 相似文献
15.
16.
W. Scott Bauman C. Mitchell Conover Don R. Cox 《The Journal of Financial Research》2002,25(2):169-186
Previous research finds that large companies previously judged to be excellent growth companies have subsequently been poor investments. We examine small companies selected by Business Week on the basis of multiple criteria used in annual articles featuring highly rated growth companies. We study the investment performance over the three years before eleven annual Business Week publications and the three years after publication. We find positive excess returns in the pre‐publication period, but negative excess returns in the post‐publication period. This reversal in investment performance appears to be due to a mean‐reversion tendency in operating performance, in which the earnings and the past rates of return on capital of such companies subsequently decrease significantly. 相似文献
17.
In the presence of foreign factor ownership tariffs change not only the terms of (goods) trade but also income flows between countries. Assume that only the home country owns factors abroad. Then the optimal tariff is negative if and only if foreign factor ownership entails trade-pattern reversals. Trade-pattern reversals are neither a necessary nor a sufficient condition for a negative optimal tariff if the foreign country owns factors in the home country. Changes in the home country's tariff shift the foreign country's offer curve. This adds a new dimension to optimal tariff analysis. 相似文献
18.
19.
J. J. Graafland 《De Economist》1992,140(4):501-514
Summary In most traditional macroeconomic models for The Netherlands the wage equation is specified by a Phillips curve, in which wage growth is negatively related to the unemployment rate. This paper shows, however, that wage formation can better be described by the so-called wage curve, in which the wage level, instead of wage growth, depends negatively on the unemployment rate.The author thanks S.K. Kuipers and D.A.G. Draper and other colleagues of the Central Planning Bureau for their useful comments. 相似文献
20.