全文获取类型
收费全文 | 3521篇 |
免费 | 49篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 748篇 |
工业经济 | 231篇 |
计划管理 | 650篇 |
经济学 | 774篇 |
综合类 | 20篇 |
运输经济 | 49篇 |
旅游经济 | 63篇 |
贸易经济 | 567篇 |
农业经济 | 159篇 |
经济概况 | 309篇 |
出版年
2024年 | 22篇 |
2023年 | 46篇 |
2022年 | 17篇 |
2021年 | 44篇 |
2020年 | 83篇 |
2019年 | 106篇 |
2018年 | 133篇 |
2017年 | 113篇 |
2016年 | 117篇 |
2015年 | 77篇 |
2014年 | 117篇 |
2013年 | 412篇 |
2012年 | 150篇 |
2011年 | 157篇 |
2010年 | 128篇 |
2009年 | 165篇 |
2008年 | 145篇 |
2007年 | 133篇 |
2006年 | 123篇 |
2005年 | 112篇 |
2004年 | 98篇 |
2003年 | 92篇 |
2002年 | 88篇 |
2001年 | 82篇 |
2000年 | 69篇 |
1999年 | 71篇 |
1998年 | 78篇 |
1997年 | 59篇 |
1996年 | 39篇 |
1995年 | 51篇 |
1994年 | 55篇 |
1993年 | 29篇 |
1992年 | 33篇 |
1991年 | 21篇 |
1990年 | 26篇 |
1989年 | 19篇 |
1988年 | 20篇 |
1987年 | 17篇 |
1986年 | 20篇 |
1985年 | 22篇 |
1984年 | 19篇 |
1983年 | 23篇 |
1982年 | 21篇 |
1981年 | 12篇 |
1980年 | 9篇 |
1979年 | 17篇 |
1978年 | 12篇 |
1977年 | 10篇 |
1976年 | 11篇 |
1973年 | 9篇 |
排序方式: 共有3570条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
991.
Today, less than 3% of the 250,000 plant varieties available to agriculture are in use. Sources of (agricultural) biodiversity are under threat and disappearing in many regions. Increasing industrialisation of agriculture and top-down agricultural research have contributed to this dependence on a relatively few plant varieties. This article argues that new approaches to agricultural development research are needed to conserve agricultural diversity, improve crops, and produce food of quality for all. Such an approach should enable small farmers on marginal lands to participate as equal partners alongside agricultural scientists, fairly sharing their know-how, expertise and seeds. Three case studies illustrate how farmers and plant breeders are working together in a diversity of agro-ecological, socio-economic and political contexts to put these new approaches into practice. New forms of collaboration are producing an increase in diversity and a number of promising improved varieties in terms of yields, agronomic traits and taste. These varieties are showing better adaptation to the local environmental conditions without requiring extra external inputs. Long-term success requires that these efforts be backed up by supportive policies, by actions to ensure that policies are implemented, and where necessary by related legislation. 相似文献
992.
Dan S. Chiaburu Jason L. Huang Holly M. Hutchins Richard G. Gardner 《International Journal of Training and Development》2014,18(1):37-52
Trainees' knowledge gains represent an important outcome in human resource development. In this research, we tested a model examining the joint influence of social desirability (impression management, self‐deception) and motives (need for power, need for approval) on trainees' self‐reported knowledge gain. We conducted a study with respondents who reported information related to individual differences and took a training program and reported their knowledge gain in domains that were both related and unrelated to the training program. Trainee unrelated knowledge gain was a function of the joint influence of individual predispositions (to impression manage or engage in self‐deception) and motives (need for power, approval). Our findings suggest that impression management and self‐deception are insufficient to influence respondents' reports of unrelated knowledge but do yield predictable patterns when examined with respondents' motives. We discuss these results and implications for human resource development research and practice. 相似文献
993.
Andrew Cheon 《Economics & Politics》2019,31(3):403-427
National oil companies (NOCs) have invested hundreds of billions of dollars in foreign oil and gas assets. Why have some governments increased their NOC outward investments, while others have not? I argue that domestic structures can influence a government's calculus that potential benefits, such as added revenues and fuel supply, outweigh potential costs, such as information asymmetries and inefficiencies associated with NOCs. Nationally, partisan competition limits democratic tolerance for failures by NOCs. Bureaucratically, overlapping authority in energy policy undermines coherent NOC governance. Based on investments by NOCs hailing from 79 countries, 2000–2013, I find robust evidence for the national hypothesis. 相似文献
994.
Is attack the best form of defence? A competing risks analysis of acquisition activity in the UK 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
Dickerson Andrew P.; Gibson Heather D.; Tsakalotos Euclid 《Cambridge Journal of Economics》2003,27(3):337-357
The primary purpose of this paper is to investigate whethercompanies can use acquisition as a strategy to reduce theirlikelihood of take-over. The determinants of making an acquisitionand being taken over are modelled for the first time withina competing risks framework using two large samples of UK manufacturingcompanies which together cover most of the post-World War IIperiod up to 1990. Our results indicate that, ceteris paribus,companies which make acquisitions can significantly reduce theirconditional probability of being taken over by around one-third,largely through the impact that acquisition has on corporatesize. In this sense, attack, through acquisition, is the bestform of defence against take-over. 相似文献
995.
I suggest the idea of a reporting function, r(.), from reality to feelings. The ‘happiness’ literature claims we have demonstrated diminishing marginal utility of income. I show not, and that knowing r(.)'s curvature is crucial. A quasi-experiment on heights is studied. 相似文献
996.
Andrew J. Lazarus Daniel E. Loeb James G. Propp Walter R. Stromquist Daniel H. Ullman 《Games and Economic Behavior》1999,27(2):133
ARichman gameis a combinatorial game in which, rather than alternating moves, the two players bid for the privilege of making the next move. The theory of such games is a hybrid between the classical theory of games (von Neumann, Morgenstern, …) and the combinatorial theory of games (Berlekamp, Conway, Guy, …). We expand upon our previous work by considering games with infinitely many positions as well as several variants including thePoorman variantin which the high bidder pays a third party (rather than the other player).Journal of Economic LiteratureClassification Number: C7. 相似文献
997.
Using a sample of 1,651 US households, we explore some determinants of willingness to pay (WTP) for climate change mitigation
programs. Our mail survey had a relatively low response rate, so we first use several additional data sources to build a detailed
sample selection model. This model uses features of the survey instrument, measures of geographic vulnerability to climate
change, seasonality, the political mix in the county, attributes of the address or addressee, and a set of factor scores from
an extensive factor analysis of all census tracts in the US. We estimate this model jointly with a model to explain climate
policy preferences as a function of the domestic and international distribution of policy costs as well as the climate change
impacts that each respondent believes will occur under a policy of business-as-usual. Despite statistically significant patterns
of nonresponse, selectivity effects are minimal in this case. WTP for climate change mitigation is greater when the domestic
incidence of mitigation costs is borne mostly through higher energy taxes. It is also greater when costs are understood to
be shared internationally with other groups of countries, rather than being borne mostly by a country group including the
US. People are generally more willing to pay for climate change mitigation if they believe that the harm caused by climate
change impacts will be substantial, rather than just moderate.
The assistance of former UCLA undergraduate students Ivka Adam, Tashi Ghale, Michelle Gogolewski, Vilija Gulbinas, and Lindy
Olsson was essential to survey development and administration. This paper is based upon work supported in part by the National
Science Foundation under Grant No. 9818875 to UCLA, with additional support from the Raymond F. Mikesell Foundation at the
University of Oregon. Any opinions, findings, and conclusions or recommendations expressed in this paper are those of the
authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of either the National Science Foundation or ICF International. 相似文献
998.
Andrew T. Nappi 《The Journal of economic education》2013,44(2):82-88
In an unusual study, Professor Nappi attempts to measure the effectiveness of teacher-made materials in increasing the economic knowledge of elementary school pupils. In addition, he asks whether special training for teachers using the materials results in greater pupil learning as well. Finally, he seeks to determine the extent to which the teacher's understanding of economics (as measured by the Test of Economic Understanding published by Science Research Associates) brings about a change in pupil knowledge. Experimental and control groups were established for purposes of this study, and the pupil change scores were adjusted for differences in mental ability. It was found that, ceteris paribus, the materials, the special training for teachers, and teacher knowledge of economics all resulted in “comparative advantages” for experimental group pupils. 相似文献
999.
In recent years, academic staff unions and associations have argued for higher salaries for academics on the grounds that existing salaries have not kept pace with inflation, are well below commercial salaries and, most glaringly, are much lower than the salaries of their overseas counterparts. However, most international comparisons are made based on exchange rate conversions, which is inappropriate since purchasing power differentials are only reflected in exchange rates in the long term. Furthermore, the volatility of exchange rates make such conversions highly inaccurate. A comparison is provided of real academic salaries by converting the nominal salaries in each country to their purchasing power equivalents, using the Big Mac Index. Our results show that real academic salaries are highest in Hong Kong and Singapore, relative to the developed countries, while Hong Kong tax and social security deductions are lowest. Furthermore, real salary levels, combined with intrinsic considerations such as the quality-of-life, indicate that Canada and New Zealand are unattractive places for visiting/migrating academics, while Australia and the USA are relatively attractive. It is suggested that these findings could be of use to policy-makers and academic unions in salary negotiations, as well as academics making relocation decisions. 相似文献
1000.
The paper re-examines Rogoff's [Rogoff, K., 1985. The Optimal Degree of Commitment to an Intermediate Monetary Target. Quarterly Journal of Economics 100, 1169–1189.] influential monetary policy result. It shows that responses of a conservative central banker and the resulting macroeconomic outcomes may be substantially different if interactions with (ambitious) fiscal policy are taken into account. 相似文献