全文获取类型
收费全文 | 4185篇 |
免费 | 17篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 923篇 |
工业经济 | 294篇 |
计划管理 | 637篇 |
经济学 | 730篇 |
综合类 | 29篇 |
运输经济 | 100篇 |
旅游经济 | 279篇 |
贸易经济 | 857篇 |
农业经济 | 67篇 |
经济概况 | 279篇 |
邮电经济 | 7篇 |
出版年
2024年 | 42篇 |
2023年 | 54篇 |
2022年 | 26篇 |
2021年 | 47篇 |
2020年 | 107篇 |
2019年 | 159篇 |
2018年 | 177篇 |
2017年 | 183篇 |
2016年 | 172篇 |
2015年 | 113篇 |
2014年 | 190篇 |
2013年 | 662篇 |
2012年 | 198篇 |
2011年 | 200篇 |
2010年 | 182篇 |
2009年 | 191篇 |
2008年 | 143篇 |
2007年 | 112篇 |
2006年 | 80篇 |
2005年 | 89篇 |
2004年 | 86篇 |
2003年 | 93篇 |
2002年 | 109篇 |
2001年 | 61篇 |
2000年 | 46篇 |
1999年 | 49篇 |
1998年 | 49篇 |
1997年 | 38篇 |
1996年 | 44篇 |
1995年 | 42篇 |
1994年 | 34篇 |
1993年 | 42篇 |
1992年 | 33篇 |
1991年 | 39篇 |
1990年 | 17篇 |
1989年 | 18篇 |
1988年 | 19篇 |
1987年 | 17篇 |
1986年 | 19篇 |
1985年 | 20篇 |
1984年 | 18篇 |
1983年 | 21篇 |
1982年 | 21篇 |
1981年 | 22篇 |
1980年 | 16篇 |
1979年 | 16篇 |
1978年 | 13篇 |
1977年 | 16篇 |
1973年 | 10篇 |
1971年 | 10篇 |
排序方式: 共有4202条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
31.
A new mean‐risk hedge ratio based on the concept of generalized semivariance (GSV) is proposed. The proposed mean‐GSV (M‐GSV) hedge ratio is consistent with the GSV‐based risk–return model developed by Fishburn (1977), Bawa (1975, 1978), and Harlow and Rao (1989). The M‐GSV hedge ratio can also be considered an extension of the GSV‐minimizing hedge ratio considered by De Jong, De Roon, and Veld (1997) and Lien and Tse (1998, 2000). The M‐GSV hedge ratio is estimated for Standard & Poor's (S&P) 500 futures and compared to six other widely used hedge ratios. Because all the hedge ratios considered are known to converge to the minimum‐variance (Johnson) hedge ratio under joint normality and martingale conditions, tests for normality and martingale conditions are carried out. The empirical results indicate that the joint normality and martingale hypotheses do not hold for the S&P 500 futures. The M‐GSV hedge ratio varies less than the GSV hedge ratio for low and relevant levels of risk aversion. Furthermore, the M‐GSV hedge ratio converges to a value different from the values of the other hedge ratios for higher values of risk aversion. © 2001 John Wiley & Sons, Inc. Jrl Fut Mark 21: 581–598, 2001 相似文献
32.
King Fuei Lee 《The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance》2013,53(2):202-218
This paper investigates the relationship between demographic changes and the long-run returns of dividend-yield investment strategies. We hypothesise that in a world where components of wealth are mentally treated as being non-fungible, the preference for high dividend-paying stocks by older investors means that the excess returns of high dividend-yielding stocks, relative to other stocks, should be positively related to demographic clientele variation. In particular, we find that, consistent with the behavioural life-cycle hypothesis, long-run returns of dividend-yield investment strategies are positively driven by changes in the proportion of the older population. Our results are robust when controlled for the Fama–French factors, inflation rate, consumption growth rate, interest rates, tax clienteles, time trend and alternative definitions of both dividend-yield strategies and demographic variation. 相似文献
33.
Focusing on foreign ownership in the private firm, we examine the Cournot-Bertrand comparison in a mixed oligopolistic market with vertical market structure. We have found that if public and private firms were charged with uniform price for their inputs, then Cournot-Bertrand ranking in market outcomes confirms those obtained by Ghosh and Mitra (2010). This implies that under uniform pricing in the upstream sector, the vertical market structure does not have substantial influences on Cournot-Bertrand ranking. However, if discriminatory pricing is adopted, firm's profits, output, and social welfare are often reversed to those obtained from uniform pricing in the upstream sector. Given the closeness of products, if the share of foreign ownership is sufficiently low, social welfare in Cournot competition can exceed that of Bertrand competition, contrasting with the standard welfare ranking that Bertrand welfare is strictly higher than Cournot. This implies that Cournot competition can be more socially desirable than Bertrand in mixed oligopoly with vertical market structure if discriminatory pricing scheme is adopted by foreign upstream monopolists. 相似文献
34.
This study decomposes the nonparametric Malmquist productivity index for 36 Korean manufacturing sectors into two components: technological change and technical efficiency change. The empirical results show that while each sector displays quite different growth patterns, productivity growth is dominated by technological change. Technological change is found to have a negative correlation with efficiency change. Secondary regression performed in this study identifies the relationship between productivity growth measures and several key policy variables, such as effective protection rate, market concentration, and so forth. The productivity estimates are compared with those of the conventional Törnqvist productivity index. 相似文献
35.
This study presents the nonlinear relationship that exists between financial development and economic growth. This study applies
the flexible nonlinear regression model of Hamilton (Econometrica 69(3):537–573, 2001) because it imposes no specification
restrictions. Two empirical results are obtained. First, an inverted U-shaped relation between banking sector development
and economic growth is identified. Namely, the two variables are positively linked before the turning point, but negatively
linked after it. Second, a positive relationship with asymmetric √-shape between stock market development and economic growth
is found. 相似文献
36.
37.
Ivan E. Brick Hong-Yi Chen Chia-Hsun Hsieh Cheng-Few Lee 《Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting》2016,47(2):369-393
The growth rate plays an important role in determining a firm’s asset and equity values, nevertheless the basic assumptions of the growth rate estimation model are less well understood. In this paper, we demonstrate that the model makes strong assumptions regarding the financing mix of the firm. In addition, we discuss various methods to estimate firms’ growth rate, including arithmetic average method, geometric average method, compound-sum method, continuous regression method, discrete regression method, and inferred method. We demonstrate that the arithmetic average method is very sensitive to extreme observations, and the regression methods yield similar but somewhat smaller estimates of the growth rate compared to the compound-sum method. Interestingly, the ex-post forecast shows that arithmetic average method (compound-sum method) yields the best (worst) performance with respect to estimating firm’s future dividend growth rate. Firm characteristics, like size, book-to-market ratio, and systematic risk, have significant influence on the forecast errors of dividend and sales growth rate estimation. 相似文献
38.
We show how to obtain coherent structural-form (SF) exclusion restrictions using the reduced-form (RF) parameter ratios. It will be shown that an over-identified SF corresponds to a group of regressors sharing the same RF ratio value; those regressors should be excluded jointly from the SF. If there is no group structure, then the SF is just-identified;
in this case, however, it is no longer clear which regressor should be excluded. Hence, just-identified SF’s are more arbitrary than over-identified SF’s in terms of exclusion restrictions. This is in stark contrast to the notion that the former is less arbitrary than the latter,
because the former excludes fewer regressors. We formalize these points, and then suggest to find the number of modes in the
estimated RF ratios as a way to find groups in the ratios. For this purpose, an informal graphical method using a kernel nonparametric
method and a formal modality test are employed. An empirical example with selling price in a residential real estate market
and duration on the market as two endogenous variables is provided.
The authors are grateful to the editor and two anonymous referees for their comments 相似文献
39.
Hwok-Aun Lee 《Asian Economic Policy Review》2023,18(1):97-119
Malaysia's New Economic Policy (NEP), promulgated in 1971, established a two-pronged national social justice agenda of poverty reduction, and social restructuring or pro-Bumiputera affirmative action. This distinction of these policy objectives must be appreciated, but various misconceptions, especially regarding affirmative action, have resulted in polarization and stalemate after 50 years of the NEP. Social justice and affirmative action must be conceptualized and evaluated with clarity and rigor, with policy objectives, mechanisms and outcomes aligned. Malaysia needs to systematically formulate a new social justice paradigm, building on the NEP and anchored on the principles of equality and fairness. In the affirmative action sphere, this framework must focus on developing capability and competitiveness, and balance identity, need and merit in the allocation of opportunity. 相似文献
40.
This study revisits purchasing power parity (PPP) theory for 20 African countries using panel asymmetric nonlinear unit root test proposed by Emirmahmutoglu and Omay (2014), through the sequential panel selection method of Chortareas and Kapetanios (2009). While standard panel unit root tests fail to support the PPP, the empirical results from panel asymmetric nonlinear unit root test do support the PPP. However, additional tests reveal that support in all 20 African countries is mostly due to stationarity of the real effective exchange rates of Ghana and Rwanda where the adjustment process towards equilibrium is nonlinear and asymmetric. 相似文献