首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   2981篇
  免费   101篇
财政金融   418篇
工业经济   178篇
计划管理   592篇
经济学   663篇
综合类   11篇
运输经济   18篇
旅游经济   27篇
贸易经济   560篇
农业经济   117篇
经济概况   459篇
邮电经济   39篇
  2021年   29篇
  2020年   49篇
  2019年   60篇
  2018年   77篇
  2017年   72篇
  2016年   74篇
  2015年   40篇
  2014年   82篇
  2013年   369篇
  2012年   106篇
  2011年   119篇
  2010年   103篇
  2009年   122篇
  2008年   99篇
  2007年   127篇
  2006年   88篇
  2005年   72篇
  2004年   88篇
  2003年   85篇
  2002年   80篇
  2001年   55篇
  2000年   50篇
  1999年   56篇
  1998年   49篇
  1997年   47篇
  1996年   47篇
  1995年   27篇
  1994年   23篇
  1993年   36篇
  1992年   26篇
  1991年   22篇
  1990年   23篇
  1989年   22篇
  1988年   23篇
  1987年   24篇
  1986年   29篇
  1985年   39篇
  1984年   33篇
  1983年   32篇
  1982年   26篇
  1981年   19篇
  1980年   32篇
  1979年   25篇
  1978年   26篇
  1977年   18篇
  1975年   25篇
  1973年   18篇
  1972年   19篇
  1971年   16篇
  1969年   17篇
排序方式: 共有3082条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
201.
The paper combines insight from new trade theory and R&D-based endogenous growth models to argue that there are ambiguous growth effects of trade liberalization between countries that differ in terms of the size of their home markets. In particular, trade liberalization may reduce R&D incentives in countries with low purchasing power without invoking parallel increases in countries with high purchasing power. The paper also considers the case of imperfect international knowledge spillovers, and demonstrates that complete trade liberalization may affect the growth rate negatively.  相似文献   
202.
203.
Summary Postwar economic development in Europe can be subdivided in two periods. In the first subperiod 1950–1973 growth is determined by catching up vis-d-vis the US. The second subperiod 1973–1993 is characterised by a reorientation with respect to the international division of labour. This sets the stage for future developments, which are presented in the form of three different scenarios. In the European Decline scenario Europe cannot match developments in the US and Japan. As appears from a scenario called Fortress Europe import protection provides no sensible solution. To compete on a world scale Europe needs more technological dynamics as sketched in the European Recovery scenario. Calculations of future paths are based on the WorldScan model of the Central Planning Bureau.Theo van de Klundert is Professor of Economics at Tilburg University. Ben Geurts and Hans Timmer are staff members of the Central Planning Bureau, The Hague. We are indebted to Martin Fase and Simon Kuipers for useful comments on an earlier version of the paper.  相似文献   
204.
Summary Neo-classical economic theory shows that managed trade or protectionism is (almost) always welfare decreasing. However, measurements of the welfare costs of protectionism based on neo-classical models seem to suggest that these costs are quite small. We discuss general new insights and developments in the theory, policy and empiricism of international trade. The observation that intra-industry trade and the services sector are important has led to a shift in theory away from constant returns to scale and perfect competition towards economies of scale and scope, externalities, market imperfections, and imperfect competition. Although this, in principle, opens the door to beneficial government intervention in the economic process, we emphasize that the true costs of protection can potentially be much higher than is generally acknowledged as a result of the above mentioned shift.We would like to thank, without implicating, Martin Fase, Harry Garretsen, Catrinus Jepma, Simon Kuipers, Ger Lanjouw, Tenn Schmidt, Albert de Vaal, and Jean-Marie Viaene for stimulating conversations and useful suggestions. We thank Thijs Knaap for excellent research assistance.  相似文献   
205.
206.
Measures of national product can be misleading because there is nonmarket production. There are also distortions due to transactional activities, which are expenditures to support transactions, not actual output consumed. For 1950–89, this study recalculates output for the United States, adjusting for transactional activities and nonmarket production. Due to relatively rapid growth in transactional activities, GNP overstates output growth in the 1950s; because there was slow expansion of transactional activities in the early 1970s, GNP understates actual output. Since 1974, increases in transactional activities and shifts to market production lead GNP to exaggerate improvement of "actual" output per capita.  相似文献   
207.
208.
209.
210.
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号