首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   136篇
  免费   3篇
财政金融   19篇
工业经济   8篇
计划管理   22篇
经济学   14篇
综合类   1篇
贸易经济   51篇
农业经济   12篇
经济概况   11篇
邮电经济   1篇
  2020年   2篇
  2019年   5篇
  2017年   5篇
  2016年   3篇
  2014年   7篇
  2013年   18篇
  2012年   6篇
  2011年   5篇
  2010年   4篇
  2009年   3篇
  2008年   10篇
  2007年   3篇
  2006年   2篇
  2005年   3篇
  2004年   1篇
  2003年   3篇
  2001年   1篇
  2000年   2篇
  1999年   1篇
  1998年   1篇
  1997年   1篇
  1996年   2篇
  1995年   1篇
  1994年   2篇
  1993年   2篇
  1992年   2篇
  1990年   2篇
  1989年   2篇
  1988年   2篇
  1986年   1篇
  1985年   3篇
  1984年   1篇
  1983年   2篇
  1982年   3篇
  1981年   1篇
  1980年   3篇
  1979年   2篇
  1978年   2篇
  1977年   3篇
  1975年   1篇
  1974年   1篇
  1973年   2篇
  1972年   2篇
  1970年   2篇
  1967年   1篇
  1963年   1篇
  1962年   1篇
  1943年   1篇
  1940年   1篇
  1918年   1篇
排序方式: 共有139条查询结果,搜索用时 390 毫秒
101.
Recently, some economists have come to view economic development as a process of ongoing structural change which has self-organisational features. What is required is evidence concerning the self-organisational character of economic development. In other words, is economic growth associated with growth in the complexity of its structure and with a parallel rise in organisational interdependence? An extended version of qualitative input-output analysis, termed Minimal Flow Analysis (MFA), is used in this paper to analyse the structural linkages and changes that have occurred in the Queensland economy over the last two decades. The MFA evidence confirms that there has been a steady increase in the complexity of the Queensland economy. Economic coordination has occurred, to an increasing extent, through market intermediation. From a self-organisational perspective, it is clear that the Queensland economy has followed a rapid and coherent developmental path, marked by the emergence of bonded structures in its core and increasing complexity on its periphery.  相似文献   
102.
This paper develops a general approach to analyzing the expansion path of preferences. A framework is introduced that looks for modelling risk aversion using a normed distance defined on a real vector space. In this approach the distance between any two indifference curves is unambiguously measured by the absolute difference of a function depending on the utility. This forms a natural basis for analyzing the special case of an ? p norm. Furthermore, a link is made to the limit case of p = ?? allowing to encompass as a special case CARA preferences. Finally, some notion of normed equivalent is proposed and duality results are established.  相似文献   
103.
Zusammenfassung Der vorliegende Beitrag zeigt, daß es auch in der BRD etliche empirische Indizien gibt, welche für die aus den USA bakannte These «die Armen zahlen mehr» sprechen. Nach einer kurzen Erläuterung dieser These sowie der sie stützenden Einzelhypothesen und der Erörterung der dafür sprechenden empirischen Indizien in der BRD, wird schließlich die Frage aufgeworfen, ob die Verbraucherpolitik in der BRD nicht stärker auf die besonderen Probleme sozial schwacher Konsumenten ausgerichtet werden soll, um damit zugleich in Übereinstimmung mit sozialpolitischen Zielsetzungen deren Lebenslage zu verbessern.
The poor pay more — an ignored problem of consumer policy in the Federal Republic of Germany
The aim of this article is to focus the attention of consumer research and consumer policy in West Germany on the special disadvantages of low-income consumers. These disadvantages are well known in U. S. consumer and poverty research since the pioneering study in this field by Caplovitz (The Poor Pay More) but seem to be still largely ignored in West Germany.Surveying the available empirical knowledge on income differences and consumer behaviour in West Germany, four main factors can be identified which cause low-income consumers to pay more for the same goods (T1), or to get goods of lower quality, i.e., less value for the same amount of money (T2), than better-off middle-class consumers do.Firstly, in West Germany as in other western countries, low-income consumers, especially low-educated consumers, seem to be less informed than better educated middle-class consumers about market conditions, shopping opportunities, prices, and quality of goods. So they may have a greater risk of uneconomical buying. Remarkably, low-income consumers do not utilize the consumer's advice bureau or consumer information offered by the Stiftung Warentest to the extent that middle-class consumers do.Secondly, low-income consumers more frequently than middle-class consumers shop for food and daily necessities in small stores in their neighbourhood, more often buying in small quantities. Shopping in this way, goods are more expensive than by buying larger quantities in supermarkets or discount-stores. Interviews with low-income consumers in Munich (Studiengruppe für Sozialforschung, 1974) showed that this particular shopping behaviour is not mainly due to the lack of market information or to a preference by low-income consumers for personal contacts at shopping, as is sometimes maintained, but rather stems from budget restrictions which prevent large-scale buying, and from transportation problems facing low-income consumers without an automobile, especially in urban low-income areas and in rural settlements without discount-stores or the like.Thirdly, there is some evidence to suggest that low-income consumers in West Germany more frequently buy on instalment credit, which is supposed to be more costly than cash-payments or banking credits preferred by middle-class consumers.Fourthly, there is some empirical evidence in West Germany that low-income consumers, mostly low-educated, in contrast to middle-class consumers largely lack consumer know-how and shopping sophistication. So it can be assumed that low-income consumers are more frequently caught in unplanned and unfavourable purchases by persuasion of salesmen or pedlars. Presumably they also, more often than middle-class consumers, abstarin from taking action when dissatisfied. It is worth nothing, though, that the latest empirical findings in West Germany do not support the widespread view that low-income consumers do less household planning and budgeting and therefore more frequently do uneconomical shopping than middle-class consumers. Indeed, in the incidence of household planning in the country there seems to be no significant differences by income level. As strict household planning in West Germany is generally rare, in this respect one may only presume that many poor consumers pay more than would be necessary by careful income spending (T3).Referring to these findings, the recommendation is made that public consumer policy in the Federal Republic of Germany to an increasing extent should face up to the disadvantages of low-income consumers and attempt to contribute to the reduction of real-income poverty. As scientific knowledge on this issue is still very sparse in West Germany, the article closes with a demand for further research in the field.


Hermann Scherl ist wissenschaftlicher Assistent am Institut für Staats-und Versicherungswissenschaft der Universität Erlangen-Nürnberg (D — 8520 Erlangen, Kochstraße 4).  相似文献   
104.
Ohne Zusammenfassung
XIII. Soziologie und Kultur, Politik und Geschichte
  相似文献   
105.
106.
MNCs with plans for marketing within the EC after 1992 may want to prepare now for developments stemming from a directive calling for a tough stand on product liability within the European Community.  相似文献   
107.
Recent studies assessing plausible futures for agricultural markets and global food security have had contradictory outcomes. To advance our understanding of the sources of the differences, 10 global economic models that produce long‐term scenarios were asked to compare a reference scenario with alternate socioeconomic, climate change, and bioenergy scenarios using a common set of key drivers. Several key conclusions emerge from this exercise: First, for a comparison of scenario results to be meaningful, a careful analysis of the interpretation of the relevant model variables is essential. For instance, the use of “real world commodity prices” differs widely across models, and comparing the prices without accounting for their different meanings can lead to misleading results. Second, results suggest that, once some key assumptions are harmonized, the variability in general trends across models declines but remains important. For example, given the common assumptions of the reference scenario, models show average annual rates of changes of real global producer prices for agricultural products on average ranging between ?0.4% and +0.7% between the 2005 base year and 2050. This compares to an average decline of real agricultural prices of 4% p.a. between the 1960s and the 2000s. Several other common trends are shown, for example, relating to key global growth areas for agricultural production and consumption. Third, differences in basic model parameters such as income and price elasticities, sometimes hidden in the way market behavior is modeled, result in significant differences in the details. Fourth, the analysis shows that agro‐economic modelers aiming to inform the agricultural and development policy debate require better data and analysis on both economic behavior and biophysical drivers. More interdisciplinary modeling efforts are required to cross‐fertilize analyses at different scales.  相似文献   
108.
This article provides an empirical analysis of the impact of European Union (EU) private food safety standards on pesticide use and farm‐level productivity among small‐scale vegetable producers in Kenya. We apply an extended three‐stage damage control production framework, accounting for multiple endogeneity problems, to farm‐level data collected from a random cross‐sectional sample of 539 small‐scale producers. Estimation results show that farmers producing vegetables for the domestic market use significantly lower quantities of pesticides than do export farmers. However, contrary to findings elsewhere, the econometric evidence here shows that both domestic and export‐oriented vegetable farmers in Kenya use pesticides at levels below the economic optimum. The results also show that the adoption of standards by export farmers does not have any significant impact on total pesticide use. However, adopter categories are distinguishable in terms of types of pesticide used, i.e. adopters use safer pesticides based on World Health Organization (WHO) classification. The third‐stage structural revenue model results demonstrate that adoption of standards has a positive and significant impact on revenue raised in vegetable production. Nevertheless, farmers producing for the export market are indistinguishable from those producing for the domestic farmers in terms of the total revenue earned from producing vegetables during the rainy season, on a ‘per acre’ basis. Although standards can potentially prevent resource‐poor smallholders from maintaining their position in the lucrative export markets, they can also result in positive changes in the production systems of those small‐scale farmers who adopt it, as shown by these results.  相似文献   
109.
As entrepreneurship researchers compete to have their work published and universities strive to attract the best entrepreneurship scholars, it is appropriate to examine what makes entrepreneurship research interesting. Interesting studies are usually defined as well-crafted and well-written studies that challenge established knowledge, and produce new theories and findings. This paper examines entrepreneurship scholars’ views on the characteristics of interesting entrepreneurship research by means of a qualitative approach. Eight focus group interviews comprising junior and senior entrepreneurship scholars were conducted. A core finding is that interesting studies must be relevant to practice. However, the institutionalization of entrepreneurship as an academic field has favoured rigour at the cost of relevance, leading to scholars’ frustration with the rigour–relevance gap. In this paper, we analyse various dimensions of interestingness and reflect on strategies for overcoming the rigour–relevance gap, with particular focus on the creation of applicative knowledge.  相似文献   
110.
Utilizing time series data for a panel of 22 emerging countries and applying Granger causality tests, this paper extends the relationship between central bank independence (CBI) and uncertainties of inflation by including the phenomena of exchange rates and foreign capital flows. There are two specific objectives of this investigation. The first objective is to see whether uncertainty of inflation induces volatility of exchange rates, and vice versa, under differing degrees of CBI. The second objective is to explore whether the dynamics of the former relationship influence foreign capital flows in turn and, if so, whether the extent of CBI plays any role in shaping that influence. The period of study spans the years 1968 through 2013. Conditional variances for inflation and exchange rates define proxies for uncertainties of inflation and exchange rates in the empirical analysis. Additionally, annual inflows of foreign direct investment (FDI) provide measures for foreign capital flows in the analysis. Results of causality tests for high and low CBI country subgroups show interesting differences. For the high CBI countries, uncertainty of inflation and uncertainty of exchange rates do not share any causal relationship whatsoever between them. However, a weak link runs from FDI to uncertainties of inflation in the long run. This may be indicative of the disciplined monetary policy and tamed inflation in these countries. Contrastingly, for the low CBI countries, there is strong evidence of causal links running from uncertainties of inflation to uncertainties of exchange rates on the one hand and to FDI flows on the other. In addition, there is indication of a bi-directional causal link between FDI flows and exchange rates for these countries.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号