全文获取类型
收费全文 | 15105篇 |
免费 | 344篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 3021篇 |
工业经济 | 1243篇 |
计划管理 | 2562篇 |
经济学 | 3265篇 |
综合类 | 209篇 |
运输经济 | 110篇 |
旅游经济 | 260篇 |
贸易经济 | 2445篇 |
农业经济 | 719篇 |
经济概况 | 1591篇 |
信息产业经济 | 1篇 |
邮电经济 | 23篇 |
出版年
2021年 | 110篇 |
2020年 | 197篇 |
2019年 | 278篇 |
2018年 | 311篇 |
2017年 | 342篇 |
2016年 | 339篇 |
2015年 | 222篇 |
2014年 | 330篇 |
2013年 | 1616篇 |
2012年 | 440篇 |
2011年 | 530篇 |
2010年 | 451篇 |
2009年 | 512篇 |
2008年 | 451篇 |
2007年 | 424篇 |
2006年 | 368篇 |
2005年 | 333篇 |
2004年 | 308篇 |
2003年 | 332篇 |
2002年 | 351篇 |
2001年 | 302篇 |
2000年 | 350篇 |
1999年 | 318篇 |
1998年 | 334篇 |
1997年 | 306篇 |
1996年 | 296篇 |
1995年 | 268篇 |
1994年 | 234篇 |
1993年 | 247篇 |
1992年 | 238篇 |
1991年 | 255篇 |
1990年 | 238篇 |
1989年 | 177篇 |
1988年 | 168篇 |
1987年 | 166篇 |
1986年 | 189篇 |
1985年 | 280篇 |
1984年 | 237篇 |
1983年 | 221篇 |
1982年 | 185篇 |
1981年 | 202篇 |
1980年 | 179篇 |
1979年 | 183篇 |
1978年 | 190篇 |
1977年 | 135篇 |
1976年 | 151篇 |
1975年 | 124篇 |
1974年 | 114篇 |
1973年 | 105篇 |
1972年 | 81篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
31.
Close relationships between and among supply chain members are becoming more prevalent. However, there is lack of agreement in the literature and in practice concerning the characteristics of different interorganizational relationships. The resultant confusion is an obstacle to the progression of research and could cause problems among firms in a supply chain. Based on previous research and an exploratory study conducted with company executives responsible for supply chain management activities, this article seeks to introduce the concept of relationship magnitude (i.e., the extent or degree of closeness or strength of the relationship) and differentiate it from relationship type (i.e., classes of relationships that share common traits). Implications for managers and opportunities for future research are provided. 相似文献
32.
In this paper we re-examine the effect of 12b–1 payments on mutual fund expense ratios by analyzing data from 1988 through 1991. The findings are consistent with previous studies that find charges are a dead-weight cost borne by shareholders. However, we show that this cost increases over time. 相似文献
33.
34.
The objective of this paper is to examine the effects of marking‐to‐market of futures contracts on the price differential between futures and forward contracts based on the predictions of the Cox, Ingersoll and Ross (1981) (CIR) model. Cox et al ., (1981) derive a series of propositions with respect to the relationship between futures and forward prices and a set of testable implications. These are tested empirically in this paper using Australian data from November 1991 to June 1997. The results provide evidence of the presence of significant futures and forward price differences, where the futures price is consistently below the forward price. Only partial support is found for the Cox et al ., (1981) propositions, implying that the effect of marking‐to‐market is not able to fully account for the price differential. Therefore, it is not possible to rule out the influence of other institutional factors on the futures‐forward price difference. 相似文献
35.
Yolanda K. Grift 《De Economist》1988,136(2):185-204
Summary The excess burden of a tax is the diminution of utility above that which would have occurred had the tax been collected as a lump sum. Computing the excess burden for the 1983 and 1985 Dutch tax and social premium system enables a partial welfare evaluation of the recent changes in the system, the so-called Tweeverdienersmaatregelen. Based on the equivalent and compensating variation, the excess burden as a percentage of the taxes and social premiums for the 1983 and 1985 system are valued at 27010 and 84010, and 37010 and 58010 respectively. This result indicates that, welfare-theoretically, the old system seems preferable to the new one.The author wishes to thank Hans Doodeman, Paul Renaud and Jacques Siegers for their critical remarks on an earlier version of this article. 相似文献
36.
37.
Summary In 1961 Arrow, Chenery, Minhas and Solow presented their C.E.S. production function, which was based on the relation between the real wage rate and the average labour productivity. They argued that, if the aggregate production function is continuous, lineair and homogeneous, then, with perfect competition and profit maximalization prevailing, the relation between the real wage rate and the average labour productivity is reflection of the production structure. This relation can, therefore, be used for specifying the production structure.In the present paper, the same line of thought is applied to the Dutch economy. Several hypotheses on the relation between wage rate and average labour productivity are tested. Statistically, it turns out that in the Dutch economy the elasticity of substitution between capital and labour is not a constant: it declines with increasing capital-labour ratio. Two statistically acceptable production equations that have this feature are presented.The efficiency parameter appearing as an integration constant in both production equations shows a decline: with labour productivity constant, the capital-labour ratio is falling over time. This means that the relation between labour productivity and capital-labour ratio shifts over time. Another outcome of this study is that technical progress is capitalaugmenting and that it brings about 50 percent of the growth in the labour productivity.De schrijvers zijn dank verschuldigd aan Prof. Dr. F. J. de Jong voor zijn stimulerende kritiek en aan de heren J. G. Althuis, F. J. van Bolhuis, J. D. Flikweert, H. Jager en B. S. Wilpstra, assistenten bij de afdeling Algemene Economie van de Economische Faculteit der Rijksuniversiteit te Groningen, voor hun bereidwillige medewerking aan dit onderzoek. 相似文献
38.
Summary Two behavioural models of economic growth are developed: a neo-classical and a neo-keynesian (Kaldorian) one.In the neo-classical model consumers aspire to a certain level of consumption. Savings and supply of labour (man-hours) are the means for reaching this level.In the neo-keynesian model firms and households have a certain aspiration level with respect to profits and consumption, respectively. To reach these levels firms decide to invest and households to supply man-hours.In both models growth is entirely dependent on the parameters of the behaviour equations. In this respect they differ from the traditional neo-classical and neo-keynesian (Kaldorian) models, in which growth is eventually determined by autonomous technical progress and growth of the labour force. 相似文献
39.
40.
James Tobin 《De Economist》1990,138(1):1-14
Summary Jan Tinbergen originated the theory of policy in the 1950s. Here I apply it to contemporary macroeconomics. The two standard instruments of short-run demand management cannot achieve the two usual targets, full employment and price stability. With respect to those goals, these two instruments are collinear, except for small and transient effects on foreign exchange rates. But the mix of fiscal and monetary policies, relative to one another, does have important effects on the composition of national output, as between investment and consumption.I point out that policy-makers, like portfolio managers, should diversify the instruments they use when they are uncertain of their effects. I discuss some pitfalls in the empirical estimation of policy effects, especially possible misinterpretations of simple correlations, and I note that policy rules cannot be invariant to changes in macroeconomic structure. I argue that policy rules should involve responses to new information and in practice allow discretion. Finally, I suggest that Tinbergen's theory of policy needs to be extended to policy coordination among nations.Third Tinbergen Lecture delivered on October 20, 1989, in Utrecht for the Royal Netherlands Economic Association. 相似文献