全文获取类型
收费全文 | 15416篇 |
免费 | 302篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 3111篇 |
工业经济 | 1163篇 |
计划管理 | 2397篇 |
经济学 | 3293篇 |
综合类 | 519篇 |
运输经济 | 105篇 |
旅游经济 | 242篇 |
贸易经济 | 2239篇 |
农业经济 | 750篇 |
经济概况 | 1887篇 |
信息产业经济 | 1篇 |
邮电经济 | 11篇 |
出版年
2021年 | 82篇 |
2020年 | 180篇 |
2019年 | 271篇 |
2018年 | 289篇 |
2017年 | 301篇 |
2016年 | 268篇 |
2015年 | 209篇 |
2014年 | 307篇 |
2013年 | 1645篇 |
2012年 | 371篇 |
2011年 | 467篇 |
2010年 | 431篇 |
2009年 | 401篇 |
2008年 | 448篇 |
2007年 | 386篇 |
2006年 | 293篇 |
2005年 | 301篇 |
2004年 | 310篇 |
2003年 | 318篇 |
2002年 | 327篇 |
2001年 | 314篇 |
2000年 | 359篇 |
1999年 | 284篇 |
1998年 | 305篇 |
1997年 | 301篇 |
1996年 | 259篇 |
1995年 | 259篇 |
1994年 | 260篇 |
1993年 | 309篇 |
1992年 | 276篇 |
1991年 | 254篇 |
1990年 | 235篇 |
1989年 | 201篇 |
1988年 | 191篇 |
1987年 | 181篇 |
1986年 | 198篇 |
1985年 | 271篇 |
1984年 | 327篇 |
1983年 | 278篇 |
1982年 | 254篇 |
1981年 | 283篇 |
1980年 | 246篇 |
1979年 | 260篇 |
1978年 | 210篇 |
1977年 | 202篇 |
1976年 | 182篇 |
1975年 | 144篇 |
1974年 | 145篇 |
1973年 | 128篇 |
1972年 | 88篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 140 毫秒
21.
22.
23.
Using Turkish industry-level data from 1983 to 1990, we find that politically organized industries receive both higher protection and promotion than unorganized ones. Tariff rates are decreasing (increasing) in the import-penetration ratio and the absolute value of the import-demandelasticity for organized (unorganized) industries. Subsidy rates are decreasing (increasing) in the output-supply elasticity for organized (unorganized) industries. The results are consistent with the predictions of the Grossman–Helpman model and its extension in this paper. The mix of protection and promotion is inversely related to the ratio of their respective marginal deadweight cost measures. 相似文献
24.
This article uses a nonparametric test based on the arc‐sine law (see, e.g., Feller, 1965 ), which involves comparing the theoretical distribution implied by an intraday random walk with the empirical frequency distribution of the daily high/low times, in order to address the question of whether the abandonment of pit trading has been associated with greater market efficiency. If market inefficiencies result from flaws in the market microstructure of pit trading, they ought to have been eliminated by the introduction of screen trading. If, on the other hand, the inefficiencies are a reflection of investor psychology, they are likely to have survived, unaffected by the changeover. We focus here on four cases. Both the FTSE‐100 and CAC‐40 index futures contracts were originally traded by open outcry and have moved over to electronic trading in recent years, so that we are able to compare pricing behavior before and after the changeover. The equivalent contracts in Germany and Korea, on the other hand, have been traded electronically ever since their inception. Our results overwhelmingly reject the random‐walk hypothesis both for open‐outcry and electronic‐trading data sets, suggesting there has been no increase in efficiency as a result of the introduction of screen trading. One possible explanation consistent with our results would be that the index futures market is characterized by intraday overreaction. © 2004 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. Jrl Fut Mark 24:337–357, 2004 相似文献
25.
Thomas D. Willett Aida Budiman Arthur Denzau Gab-Je Jo Cesar Ramos John Thomas 《The World Economy》2004,27(1):25-44
Various claims have been made about the causes of the Asian crisis and its spread. Here, we use data on the behaviour of capital flows during the crisis to test the strong forms of four such hypotheses, that portfolio investors and hedge funds played a dominant role in initiating and/or spreading the crisis; that moral hazard kept efficient markets from predicting the crisis; and, finally, the common lender hypothesis of Kaminsky and Reinhart. In the process we also test implications of the Calvo-Mendoza model of rational investor ignorance. All are falsified as monocausal explanations. For example, portfolio investments that could not have been subject to substantial moral hazard continued to flow into Asia until very shortly before the crisis. Likewise, banks were a much larger source of capital outflows during the crisis than were portfolio investors. While falsified in their strongest forms, several of these hypotheses in less strong forms should play a role in a more nuanced analysis. It is necessary to move past simple single-factor approaches in order to produce a more complete, synthetic explanation of this episode. 相似文献
26.
In this paper we investigate the use of the structured full rank model for hedging the balance sheet of a financial institution. Simulation results suggest that the optimal hedge is insensitive to changes in parameter estimates. In addition, we hedge a portfolio of Treasury bills using both the full information covariance matrix and the structured covariance matrix. We then contrast these results with those obtained from a duration-based model. Empirical results suggest that the structured full rank model is generally more effective in hedging applications than either the full information model or duration-based model. 相似文献
27.
28.
29.
Milton D. Rosenau 《Journal of Product Innovation Management》1992,9(4):300-302
Too often companies fall into a trap when developing a list of performance specifications for a new product. Milton Rosenau calls this the best-of-the-best specification trap. The problem arises whenever a company bases a specification on the combination of the best single features observed in available competitive products. When this happens, the new product's design is driven by competition and is not derived from a unique market insight. This may not provide the basis for a sustainable advantage. Sometimes, rumors of competitive improvements may even lead to sudden changes in the specification, creating delays in the development process. A far better goal is to develop a specification that responds to an unrecognized and unfilled user need, one that adds high value to users. His points are illustrated with several examples. 相似文献
30.