全文获取类型
收费全文 | 294篇 |
免费 | 5篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 57篇 |
工业经济 | 29篇 |
计划管理 | 61篇 |
经济学 | 96篇 |
运输经济 | 2篇 |
旅游经济 | 1篇 |
贸易经济 | 41篇 |
经济概况 | 12篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 2篇 |
2022年 | 4篇 |
2021年 | 4篇 |
2020年 | 4篇 |
2019年 | 9篇 |
2018年 | 12篇 |
2017年 | 8篇 |
2016年 | 12篇 |
2015年 | 7篇 |
2014年 | 22篇 |
2013年 | 31篇 |
2012年 | 14篇 |
2011年 | 25篇 |
2010年 | 9篇 |
2009年 | 18篇 |
2008年 | 9篇 |
2007年 | 8篇 |
2006年 | 13篇 |
2005年 | 10篇 |
2004年 | 14篇 |
2003年 | 7篇 |
2002年 | 9篇 |
2001年 | 9篇 |
2000年 | 6篇 |
1999年 | 3篇 |
1998年 | 4篇 |
1997年 | 4篇 |
1996年 | 3篇 |
1995年 | 3篇 |
1994年 | 3篇 |
1993年 | 3篇 |
1992年 | 3篇 |
1990年 | 2篇 |
1985年 | 1篇 |
1984年 | 1篇 |
1983年 | 1篇 |
1982年 | 1篇 |
1975年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有299条查询结果,搜索用时 109 毫秒
21.
This paper argues that dividend yield stock return predictability is time-varying. We conjecture that such time-variation is linked to the business cycle. Employing monthly data for US sector portfolios we estimate 5-year rolling fixed window predictive regressions. The resulting series of time-varying predictive coefficients is regressed on industrial production growth and a recession dummy. Our results support the view of a negative relationship between predictability and output growth. That is the strength of the predictive relationship between returns and the dividend yield is stronger during contractionary periods, while during expansions the magnitude of the relationship declines. 相似文献
22.
The comparative static predictions of the Baron and Ferejohn [Baron, D.P., and Ferejohn, J.A., (1989). Bargaining in legislatures, American Political Science Review 83 (4), 1181-1206] model better organize behavior in legislative bargaining experiments than Gamson's Law. Regressions similar to those employed in field data produce results seemingly in support of Gamson's Law (even when using data generated by simulating agents who behave according to the Baron-Ferejohn model), but this is determined by the selection protocol which recognizes voting blocks in proportion to the number of votes controlled. Proposer power is not nearly as strong as predicted in the closed rule Baron and Ferejohn model, as coalition partners refuse to take the small shares given by the continuation value of the game. Discounting pushes behavior in the direction predicted by Baron and Ferejohn but has a much smaller effect than predicted. 相似文献
23.
Review 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
Massimo Torrigiani 《Local Economy》1994,9(2):207-208
URBAN TOURISM.
Law, C.M. 1993: Urban Tourism. Attracting Visitors to Large Cities. London: Mansell. £35.00 hardback. 相似文献
Law, C.M. 1993: Urban Tourism. Attracting Visitors to Large Cities. London: Mansell. £35.00 hardback. 相似文献
24.
Andrea Finicelli Massimo Sbracia Andrea Zaghini 《International Economics and Economic Policy》2011,8(1):93-113
The paper describes the evolution of export shares and quantifies the contribution of geographical and sectoral specialization as well as that of “competitiveness” of some industrial and emerging market economies between 1985 and 2003. While the strong growth of emerging countries as world competitors has lowered the market shares of all industrial countries, the results of a constant-market-share analysis indicate that the latter have benefited from positive specialization effects. Specifically, industrial countries gained from being specialized in fast-growing sectors (high-tech) or destinations (Asia). The magnitude of these effects, however, has been quite diversified across the main countries. Among the emerging economies, the striking export growth of China was determined by a strong rise in competitiveness that allowed the country to gain market shares across all sectors and destinations. 相似文献
25.
26.
This paper provides some empirical evidence on one of the most controversial theoretical implications of the new open economy
literature, which refers to the role of the current account in the international monetary transmission mechanism. In order
to throw some light on this issue, two structural VAR models are estimated separately for 14 industrialized countries. The
main empirical results highlight the importance of the role of nominal disturbances for current account fluctuations. Additionally,
it is found that expansionary nominal shocks generate temporary current account surpluses, whose size is positively correlated
with the openness of the individual countries. JEL no. C32, E40, F41, F42 相似文献
27.
We study the impact of “style investing” on the market for corporate control. We argue that the choice of the bidder is influenced by the fact that the merge with a firm that belongs to an investment style more popular with the market may boost the bidder's value. By using data on the flows in mutual funds, we construct a measure of popularity, which relies directly on the identification of sentiment-induced investor demand, rather than being a direct transformation of stock market data. We show that differences in popularity between bidder and target help to explain their pairing. The merger with a more popular target generates a halo effect from the target to the bidder that induces the market to evaluate the assets of the less popular bidder at the (inflated) market value of the more popular target. Both bidder and target premiums are positively related to the difference in popularity between the target and the bidder. However, the target's ability to appropriate the gain is reduced by the fact that its bargaining position is weaker when the bidder's potential for asset appreciation is higher. We document a better short- and medium-term performance of less popular firms taking over more popular firms. The bidder managers engaging in these cosmetic mergers take advantage of the window of opportunity induced by the deal to reduce their stake in the firm under convenient conditions. 相似文献
28.
Massimo Guidolin 《Quantitative Finance》2014,14(12):2135-2153
Most papers in the portfolio choice literature have examined linear predictability frameworks based on the idea that simple but flexible Vector Autoregressive (VAR) models can be expanded to produce portfolio allocations that hedge against the bull and bear dynamics typical of financial markets through careful selection of predictor variables that capture business cycles and market sentiment. Yet, a distinct literature exists that shows that non-linear econometric frameworks, such as Markov switching, are also natural tools to compute optimal portfolios arising from the existence of good and bad market states. This paper examines whether and how simple VARs can produce portfolio rules similar to those obtained under a simple Markov switching, by studying the effects of expanding both the order of the VAR and the number/selection of predictor variables included. In a typical stock-bond strategic asset allocation problem for UK data, we compute the out-of-sample certainty equivalent returns for a wide range of VARs and compare these measures of performance with those of non-linear models. We conclude that most VARs cannot produce portfolio rules, hedging demands or (net of transaction costs) out-of-sample performances that approximate those obtained from simple non-linear frameworks. 相似文献
29.
EU antitrust investigations involve a sequence of events which affect the investigated firm's market value. We model these relationships and estimate their impact on firms' share prices. On average, a surprise inspection reduces a firm's share price by 2.89%, an infringement decision reduces it by 3.57%. The Court judgments do not have a statistically significant effect. Overall, we find that the total effect of the antitrust action ranges from ?3.03% to ?4.55% of a firm's market value. Fines account for no more than 8.9% of this loss, and we conjecture that most of the loss is due to the cessation of illegal activities. 相似文献
30.
Ambiguous Games 总被引:3,自引:0,他引:3
Massimo Marinacci 《Games and Economic Behavior》2000,31(2):191
This paper introduces ambiguous games, a modification of the normal form that allows the presence of vagueness in players' beliefs over the opponents' choice of strategies. An appropriate notion of equilibrium is presented, and a general existence result is proved. Journal of Economic Literature Classification Numbers: C72, D81. 相似文献