全文获取类型
收费全文 | 16779篇 |
免费 | 1篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 2649篇 |
工业经济 | 757篇 |
计划管理 | 2561篇 |
经济学 | 3886篇 |
综合类 | 482篇 |
运输经济 | 1篇 |
旅游经济 | 2篇 |
贸易经济 | 4471篇 |
经济概况 | 1355篇 |
信息产业经济 | 44篇 |
邮电经济 | 572篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 3篇 |
2020年 | 2篇 |
2019年 | 1篇 |
2018年 | 2301篇 |
2017年 | 2052篇 |
2016年 | 1205篇 |
2015年 | 92篇 |
2014年 | 87篇 |
2013年 | 57篇 |
2012年 | 437篇 |
2011年 | 1942篇 |
2010年 | 1827篇 |
2009年 | 1519篇 |
2008年 | 1514篇 |
2007年 | 1869篇 |
2006年 | 65篇 |
2005年 | 387篇 |
2004年 | 462篇 |
2003年 | 552篇 |
2002年 | 252篇 |
2001年 | 62篇 |
2000年 | 49篇 |
1998年 | 16篇 |
1997年 | 1篇 |
1996年 | 13篇 |
1986年 | 13篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
181.
This paper considers the assignment of tradable permits—representing property rights of an environmental good—to community members who are harmed by pollution generated by firms. These community members can in turn sell permits to polluters according to their personal preferences. For a special case with a sole household, market transactions between the household and polluters achieve an efficient pollution level. However, for a group of households, the decentralized market solution fails to yield social efficiency because of competitive consumption of the environmental goods. We design a revenue-sharing mechanism akin to unitization, under which market transactions also achieve efficient resource allocation. Importantly, in some cases, efficiency can be achieved even when regulators are ignorant of the private valuation of the environmental good. 相似文献
182.
We analyze optimal merger policy in R&D-intensive industries with product innovation aiming to improve the quality of products. Our results suggest that a permissive merger policy is rarely optimal in high-tech industries when the antitrust authority considers a welfare standard that balances the impact of mergers on consumers’ surplus and firms’ profits. In particular, relative to a benchmark where the effects from R&D are absent, we show that the optimal merger policy should not be substantially more permissive in the presence of those effects from R&D. 相似文献
183.
The house money effect predicts that individuals show increased risk-seeking behavior in the presence of prior windfall gains. Although the effect’s existence is widely accepted, experimental studies that compare individuals’ risk-taking behavior using house money to individuals’ risk-taking behavior using their own money produce contradictory results. This experimental field study analyzes the gambling behavior of 917 casino customers who face real losses. We find that customers who received free play at the entrance showed not higher but significantly lower levels of risk-taking behavior during their casino visit, expressed through lower average wagers. This study thus provides field evidence against the house money effect. Moreover, as a result of lower levels of risk seeking, endowed customers yield better economic results in the form of smaller own-money losses when leaving the casino. 相似文献
184.
Hock Tsen Wong 《Empirical Economics》2017,53(2):459-492
This study examines the impact of exchange rate volatility on bilateral exports of Malaysia to Singapore, China, Japan, the USA and Korea. Exchange rate volatility is estimated by an autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity model. The Johansen cointegration method and the dynamic ordinary least squares estimator are used in the estimations. There is some evidence of exchange rate volatility to have significant impact on real total exports in the long run, but more evidence of exchange rate volatility is found to have significant impact on sub-categories of real total exports in the short run. The impact of exchange rate volatility differs across bilateral exports. The impact of exchange rate volatility on exports can be negative or positive. Generally, exchange rate volatility is not harmful to bilateral exports of Malaysia. 相似文献
185.
Technology transfer is an important channel of technological change and sustainable development for countries with less innovative ability than technological leaders. This paper studies whether domestic environmental policies affect the inward technology transfer of cleaner innovation from abroad. We focus specifically on the power sector, for its important role in the decarbonization process, by looking at zero-carbon (renewable) and carbon-saving (efficient fossil) technologies for energy production. Using data on cross-country patent applications, we provide evidence that environmental policy contributes to attracting foreign cleaner technology options to OECD markets but not to non-OECD markets. We show that this is due to the nature of the implemented policy instruments. Market-based approaches positively impact technology transfer to both OECD and non-OECD economies, while non-market based approaches have at best only a weak effect in OECD countries. Domestic environmental policies may provide too weak a signal for foreign innovators in countries off the technological frontier. This calls for a strengthening of policy incentives for technology transfer in light of pressing climate change objectives. 相似文献
186.
Cortney Stephen Rodet 《Constitutional Political Economy》2017,28(2):167-192
Classic theories of comparative advantage point to factor productivity and factor abundance as determinants of specialization and trade. Likewise, geography and topography can determine trade patterns. Institutions, however, are increasingly seen as important sources of comparative advantage. A global drug prohibition regime implies that institutional quality matters more than traditional sources in the drug trade. This paper theoretically models trade patterns of illicit goods and confirms the role of institutions empirically with respect to the drug trade. In particular, illicit enterprises gain force in countries where resources are scarce, drug enforcement is uncertain, and institutions are weak in absolute terms and relative to neighboring countries. I propose several policy alternatives that emphasize economic opportunity for the poor and institutional quality that complement drug prohibition. 相似文献
187.
We estimate a dynamic factor model for the cross section of monetary and price indicators. We extract the common part of the dataset’s fluctuations and decompose it into structural shocks. We argue that one of the shocks identified has empirical properties (in terms of impulse response functions) that are fully in line with the theoretically expected relationship between money growth and inflation, confirming that the process identified has the capacity for economic interpretation. Based on this finding, we decompose recent inflationary developments in Russia into those that are associated with changes in monetary stance and other shorter-lived shocks. 相似文献
188.
Kent Jones 《International Advances in Economic Research》2018,24(4):325-338
Cuba sought economic independence from the U.S. and its reliance on sugar exports after its 1959 revolution, but subsequently developed new dependency relationships. In the meantime, Cuba remained inside the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), despite conducting most of its trade outside it. This paper explores the political economy of Cuba’s participation in the GATT and later the World Trade Organization (WTO). Documents show that Cuba sought to use its participation to gain new markets and influence in the developing world. While Cuba has gained little economically from its participation, in recent years it has diversified its exports and trade partners, and its trade interests now align more closely with WTO rules. Economic reforms will be necessary in order for Cuba to benefit. 相似文献
189.
Meng Li 《Frontiers of Economics in China》2010,5(1):96-113
As Chinese economy system has been depended more on the import of petroleum with the development of China, the change in the
price of international oil have caused concern among economists and policy makers. This paper is to present a financial Computable
General Equilibrium (CGE) model of the Chinese economy which integrates real economy and financial sectors, and to apply it
to quantitatively evaluate the impacts on Chinese economy caused by international oil price changes. And the model endogenously
determines the exchange rate, covering fixed, partially flexible, and completely flexile exchange rate system to consider
the effect of foreign oil price changes from the point of view of macro and industrial aspects. Finally, this paper presents
concluding remarks. 相似文献
190.
Fixed versus flexible election terms: explaining innovation in the timing of Canada’s election cycle
This paper argues that there is an efficiency gain underlying the recent adoption of legislation calling for a fixed 4-year governing term by the federal and most provincial governments in Canada. The efficiency gain arises from foreclosing an externality produced by the Canadian constitutional provision that sets a maximum length for a legislative term (5 years) while allowing the governing party (through the Governor General) to dissolve the House early. Because the opportunistic use of surprise can improve the governing party’s probability of winning, strategic choice can lead to elections being held at times that most disadvantage the incumbent’s rivals. Evidence from Canada is introduced suggesting that federal elections became less predictable through successive reductions in the campaign time given to competitors, thus raising the cost of this externality. The same reasoning suggests that the party most likely to propose this legislative innovation will be the party in opposition rather than in power and/or the new leader of an established party facing loss in the upcoming election. By fulfilling the fixed term even when it could benefit by calling the election early, the party establishes a precedent that raises the political cost to others of cancelling the fixed term legislation. 相似文献