首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   561篇
  免费   30篇
财政金融   90篇
工业经济   28篇
计划管理   121篇
经济学   208篇
综合类   2篇
运输经济   16篇
旅游经济   4篇
贸易经济   65篇
农业经济   9篇
经济概况   48篇
  2024年   2篇
  2023年   7篇
  2022年   8篇
  2021年   13篇
  2020年   24篇
  2019年   28篇
  2018年   26篇
  2017年   25篇
  2016年   29篇
  2015年   24篇
  2014年   25篇
  2013年   66篇
  2012年   25篇
  2011年   23篇
  2010年   26篇
  2009年   30篇
  2008年   28篇
  2007年   19篇
  2006年   17篇
  2005年   15篇
  2004年   18篇
  2003年   11篇
  2002年   13篇
  2001年   17篇
  2000年   12篇
  1999年   9篇
  1998年   6篇
  1997年   5篇
  1996年   3篇
  1995年   5篇
  1994年   2篇
  1993年   7篇
  1992年   1篇
  1991年   2篇
  1989年   2篇
  1987年   1篇
  1986年   1篇
  1985年   1篇
  1983年   1篇
  1982年   3篇
  1981年   2篇
  1979年   5篇
  1978年   1篇
  1977年   1篇
  1971年   1篇
  1970年   1篇
排序方式: 共有591条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
71.
72.
This paper is based on the results of a field work analysis of the cotton weaving industry, focusing on the relationships between performance, size and structure of firms. The results are utilized to compare models of the industries in the main European countries and to evaluate their competitiveness in the light of both standard and some non-standard efficiency criteria.  相似文献   
73.
In their very interesting paper “Set-packing problems and threshold graphs” [1] V. Chvatal and P. L. Hammer have shown that the constraints $$\begin{gathered} \sum\limits_{j = 1}^n {a_{ij} x_j \leqslant 1(i = 1,2, . . . , m)} \hfill \\ x_j \in (0,1)(j = 1,2, . . . , n) \hfill \\ \end{gathered} $$ are equivalent to the only inequality $$\begin{gathered} \sum\limits_{j - 1}^n {c_j x_j \leqslant d} \hfill \\ x_j \in (0,1)(j = 1,2, . . . , n) \hfill \\ \end{gathered} $$ if and only if the intersection graph associated with the matrix (a ij ) — see § 1 — is a threshold graph i.e. a graph none of whose induced subgraphs are isomorphic to 2K 2,P 4,C 4: As Chvatal and Hammer have shown [1], threshold graphs can be characterised in many different ways; the main result of this paper is to give a new, very simple characterisation which will enable us to test whether a graph is a threshold by a simple inspection of its incidence matrix.  相似文献   
74.
75.
76.
It is well documented that a firm may choose to offer underpriced securities in an initial public offer. An open question is why investment banks do not retain underpriced offers in their portfolio. We argue that the distribution of underpriced securities allows banks of high qualify to signal their value to their customers, promoting in this way their other product lines. We show that the total dollar value of underpriced securities distributed (rather than the percentage value) acts as the signal. We also find that, all else equal, larger customers and those with more elastic demand functions receive n larger total dollar value of underpricing.  相似文献   
77.
A tale of two Italies: ‘access-orders’ and the Italian regional divide   总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1  
ABSTRACT

This paper uses the ‘access orders’ paradigm developed by North, Wallis, and Weingast [(2009). Violence and social order: A conceptual framework for interpreting recorded human history. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press] to analyse the case of the Italian North–South economic divide. In line with their framework, we collect and discuss several social and political indicators over the long-run, at the regional level. Firstly we looked at data on the pre-conditions for the establishment of an open-access order, such as murders per capita (a proxy for control over violence), voting turnout and referendums participation (proxies for political legitimacy), and the impersonality of exchange. We then showed evidence of different access orders in the North and in the South, using the information on human capital formation, women participation in the labour market, and referendum results. On the basis of this evidence, we argue that, despite being part of the same State and subject to the same formal institutions, the North of the country progressively developed into an open-access order, while the South remained a form of limited access order.

Institutional differences are linked to specific aspects of the economic performance of the two areas, thus the ‘access order’ paradigm appears to be an effective conceptual scheme to explain the North–South economic divide.  相似文献   
78.
A well‐known debate on the Renaissance economy was held in this journal in 1962–4 between Roberto S. Lopez and Harry Miskimin on one hand and Carlo M. Cipolla on the other. More than half a century later, this topic can be reconsidered in the light of much wider information on the late medieval/early modern Italian economy. Using data on population, urbanization, prices, wages, and GDP, this article outlines the macroeconomic trends in central and northern Italy in the age of the Renaissance (1350–1550). The frequent plagues during the early Renaissance—that is, between 1348 and 1450—decimated the population, probably causing more deaths than in other European countries. Hence resources per worker increased and labour productivity, incomes, and standards of living improved remarkably. A favourable economic environment thus seems to have been a pre‐condition for the Renaissance in culture, art, and politics and the spread of new kinds of consumer demand. From the middle of the fifteenth century, living standards gradually worsened and eventually reached the low levels that had prevailed prior to the Renaissance.  相似文献   
79.
80.
We study self‐selection into politics and effort once in office of citizens with different abilities and motivations in a framework where moonlighting is allowed. We find that high‐ability motivated (public‐fit) politicians exert higher effort in politics than high‐ability non‐motivated (market‐fit) politicians, and that high‐ability citizens, both public‐fit and market‐fit, may decide to enter politics. We test our predictions using a database of Italian parliamentarians for the period 1996–2006. We find evidence of advantageous selection of both market‐fit and public‐fit parliamentarians. We also show that public‐fit parliamentarians have higher voting attendance and that only voting attendance of market‐fit parliamentarians is negatively affected by income opportunities.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号