首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   16808篇
  免费   443篇
财政金融   3109篇
工业经济   1310篇
计划管理   2880篇
经济学   3581篇
综合类   142篇
运输经济   106篇
旅游经济   294篇
贸易经济   2630篇
农业经济   769篇
经济概况   2396篇
信息产业经济   1篇
邮电经济   33篇
  2021年   118篇
  2020年   190篇
  2019年   267篇
  2018年   307篇
  2017年   354篇
  2016年   325篇
  2015年   241篇
  2014年   354篇
  2013年   1699篇
  2012年   472篇
  2011年   520篇
  2010年   459篇
  2009年   509篇
  2008年   501篇
  2007年   434篇
  2006年   415篇
  2005年   379篇
  2004年   333篇
  2003年   373篇
  2002年   348篇
  2001年   324篇
  2000年   332篇
  1999年   362篇
  1998年   321篇
  1997年   277篇
  1996年   282篇
  1995年   251篇
  1994年   252篇
  1993年   270篇
  1992年   262篇
  1991年   270篇
  1990年   212篇
  1989年   206篇
  1988年   189篇
  1987年   186篇
  1986年   187篇
  1985年   310篇
  1984年   287篇
  1983年   268篇
  1982年   245篇
  1981年   238篇
  1980年   243篇
  1979年   235篇
  1978年   188篇
  1977年   198篇
  1976年   170篇
  1975年   153篇
  1974年   152篇
  1973年   145篇
  1970年   105篇
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 328 毫秒
991.
Summary Dalenius/Gurney [1951] published necessary conditions for the stratum boundaries, so that with Neyman's optimal allocation of the sample sizen the variance of the sample mean will become a minimum. They introduced in the variance of the sample mean for the sample sizesn h the opti mal values according to Neyman and differentiated this variance with respect to the stratum boundaries. Because Neyman's allocation formula yields only feasible solutions forn h N h , the conditions ofDalenius result in wrong, i.e. nonfeasible solutions, if one of the restrictionsn h N h (h=1 (1) L) is violated.By the example of a logarithmic normal distribution with =0, =1,5 forL=2 the behaviour of the Dalenius-Neyman-minimum and that of the feasible minimum will be shown in dependence on the sampling fractionq=n/N and a critical valueq c will be given. For valuesq>q c the Dalenius-Neyman-minimum is no longer feasible.For the same logarithmic normal distribution andL=2 (1) 10 this critical sampling fractionq c will be given (section 5).For different values of andq the optimal stratum boundaries and sampling fractions are listed in section 6 forL=2;3;4.  相似文献   
992.
In the Netherlands all gambling is forbidden except in a few cases specially mentioned in the law. Time and again specialists in probability theory or statistics are called upon to testify as experts in lawsuits against law evaders. This paper discusses the part played by the experts in such legal procedures. It is pointed out that according to Dutch jurisprudence there does not exist an exclusive distinction between games of chance and games of skill. A simple declaration by an expert that a given game is largely based on chance suffices to see the game sentenced as against the law. This and various other related questions are discussed in detail and illustrated by examples taken from personal experience in the courts.  相似文献   
993.
This paper is the first attempt to analyze ITC Commissioner voting behavior on sunset reviews of antidumping cases. Sunset determinations entail greater complexity than initial antidumping investigations because ITC commissioners must account for the impact of dumping protection as well as competitive forces on industry conditions. Empirical findings indicate that ITC voting is based on both sunset regulation and nonstatutory factors. Results reveal apparent biases against Chinese competitors and poorer nations generally, and favorable treatment toward U.S. steel producers and high-wage industries. There is also evidence of preferential treatment of industries located in states of Senate oversight committee members. JEL no. F13  相似文献   
994.
Most researchers examining poverty and multilateral trade liberalizationhave had to examine average, or per capita effects, suggestingthat if per capita real income rises, poverty will fall. Thisinference can be misleading. Combining results from a new internationalcross-section consumption analysis with earnings data from householdsurveys, this article analyzes the implications of multilateraltrade liberalization for poverty in Indonesia. It finds thatthe aggregate reduction in Indonesia's national poverty headcountfollowing global trade liberalization masks a more complex setof impacts across groups. In the short run the poverty headcountrises slightly for self-employed agricultural households, asagricultural profits fail to keep up with increases in consumerprices. In the long run the poverty headcount falls for allearnings strata, as increased demand for unskilled workers liftsincomes for the formerly self-employed, some of whom move intothe wage labor market. A decomposition of the poverty changesin Indonesia associated with different countries' trade policiesfinds that reform in other countries leads to a reduction inpoverty in Indonesia but that liberalization of Indonesia'strade policies leads to an increase. The method used here canbe readily extended to any of the other 13 countries in thesample.  相似文献   
995.
Over the past decade, the distribution of household incomes has shifted so much that a much larger proportion of consumers now earn significantly higher-than-average incomes--while still falling short of being truly rich. As a result, what used to be a no-man's-land for new product introductions has in many categories become an extremely profitable "new middle ground." How can marketers capitalize on this new territory? The key, say the authors, is to rethink the positioning and design of offerings and the ways they can be brought to market. Take, for instance, how Procter & Gamble redefined the positioning map for tooth-whitening solutions. A decade ago, dental centers were popularizing expensive bleaching techniques that put the price of a professionally brightened smile in the 400 dollars range. At the low end, consumers also had the choice of whitening toothpastes that cost anywhere from 2 dollars to 8 dollars. P&G wisely positioned itself between the two ends, successfully targeting the new mass market with its 35 dollars Whitestrips. In product categories where it's clear the middle ground has already been populated, it's important for companies to design or redesign offerings to compete. An example is the Polo shirt. How do you sell a man yet another one after he's bought every color he wants? Add some features, and call it a golf shirt. Here, marketers have introduced designs based on the concept of "occasional use" in order to stand out. Finally, companies wishing to reach the "almost rich" can change how they go to market. Perhaps no mass retailer has made a stronger bid for the mass affluent than Target Stores, which has pioneered a focus the company itself characterizes as upscale discount. The strategy has made Target an everyday shopping phenomenon among well-heeled urbanites and prosperous professionals.  相似文献   
996.
Yao Chen  H. David Sherman   《Socio》2004,38(4):307-320
Using radial super-efficiency data envelopment analysis (DEA) has improved the discriminating performance across efficient decision-making units (DMUs). This paper extends the super-efficiency approach to a non-radial super-efficiency DEA (NRSE-DEA) index. NRSE-DEA is shown to be invariant to units of input (output) measurement. NRSE-DEA is illustrated here via an application to NATO burden-sharing assessment in which the DMUs are the member nations of NATO. The NRSE-DEA provides additional insights into the ranking of efficient countries, suggesting which are absorbing a particularly large share of NATO responsibilities. The NRSE-DEA generates a smaller set of efficient DMUs. This, in turn, provides more discriminatory power, a more accurate measure of super-efficiency, a more meaningful ranking of the efficient burden sharing countries, and a more reliable assessment of contributions by NATO members, amongst other policy issues.  相似文献   
997.
Summary. We provide two new, simple proofs of Afriats celebrated theorem stating that a finite set of price-quantity observations is consistent with utility maximization if, and only if, the observations satisfy a variation of the Strong Axiom of Revealed Preference known as the Generalized Axiom of Revealed PreferenceReceived: 12 June 2003, Revised: 9 October 2003, JEL Classification Numbers: D11, C60.Correspondence to: A. Fostel  相似文献   
998.
999.
1000.
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号