全文获取类型
收费全文 | 6450篇 |
免费 | 182篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 1173篇 |
工业经济 | 519篇 |
计划管理 | 1181篇 |
经济学 | 1424篇 |
综合类 | 45篇 |
运输经济 | 87篇 |
旅游经济 | 117篇 |
贸易经济 | 1123篇 |
农业经济 | 258篇 |
经济概况 | 675篇 |
邮电经济 | 30篇 |
出版年
2022年 | 29篇 |
2021年 | 41篇 |
2020年 | 82篇 |
2019年 | 108篇 |
2018年 | 143篇 |
2017年 | 151篇 |
2016年 | 161篇 |
2015年 | 113篇 |
2014年 | 166篇 |
2013年 | 703篇 |
2012年 | 241篇 |
2011年 | 249篇 |
2010年 | 238篇 |
2009年 | 272篇 |
2008年 | 220篇 |
2007年 | 204篇 |
2006年 | 208篇 |
2005年 | 194篇 |
2004年 | 182篇 |
2003年 | 186篇 |
2002年 | 162篇 |
2001年 | 158篇 |
2000年 | 151篇 |
1999年 | 145篇 |
1998年 | 129篇 |
1997年 | 130篇 |
1996年 | 136篇 |
1995年 | 100篇 |
1994年 | 108篇 |
1993年 | 108篇 |
1992年 | 95篇 |
1991年 | 81篇 |
1990年 | 81篇 |
1989年 | 71篇 |
1988年 | 70篇 |
1987年 | 53篇 |
1986年 | 65篇 |
1985年 | 94篇 |
1984年 | 96篇 |
1983年 | 73篇 |
1982年 | 70篇 |
1981年 | 62篇 |
1980年 | 76篇 |
1979年 | 64篇 |
1978年 | 48篇 |
1977年 | 40篇 |
1976年 | 44篇 |
1975年 | 33篇 |
1974年 | 26篇 |
1973年 | 33篇 |
排序方式: 共有6632条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
21.
22.
23.
24.
家乐福集团在中国开设的大型超市就像零售业中的一个"海峡"--从东方和从西方卷来的大浪交织在一起:东方--在超市一边的货架上,可以看到大量鲜活的鱼、虾、牛蛙甚至甲鱼;西方--在另一边不远的冷藏柜里,又能看到真空包装的烟熏咸肉和意大利腊肠.这个来自法国的超级零售商运用现代的模式,结合当地人的口味,在中国经营着他们的零售帝国. 相似文献
25.
26.
Peter M. Nomikos 《Intereconomics》1981,16(6):292-294
The world’s energy supplies are dependent not only on the producer countries’ production capacities and policies but also on adequate transport facilities. In fact, a shortage of vessels able to carry coal is widely expected to be a major bottleneck for the substitution of oil by coal on a large scale. Shipowner Peter M. Nomikos holds a different view. 相似文献
27.
Age‐heaping‐based numeracy indicators have served as valuable tools to derive basic human capital estimates, especially for periods where other indicators are unavailable. However, the accuracy of individual age statements usually remains unknown, and due to the lack of precise information it can only be assumed that excessive occurrence of multiples of five in age distributions reflects inferior numerical skills. This article addresses this lacuna by identifying 162 individuals in two independent data sources: self‐reported age statements and independently kept records which are based on family heritage books and church registers. This method makes it possible to identify individual misreporting and the degree of accuracy of each individual. Findings show that not everyone who reported a multiple of five was reporting an incorrect age, nor was it the case that everyone who reported an age that was not a multiple of five was reporting an accurate age. The empirical analysis shows that the commonly used binary numeracy indicator is correlated with the observed degree of accuracy in age statements, and that a more sophisticated occupational background reduces this inaccuracy. These results tentatively suggest that the commonly used binary indicator measuring age heaping is a valuable proxy for numerical skills and occupational background in a population. 相似文献
28.
29.
Based on pooled register data from Norway and Sweden, we findthat differences in unemployment duration patterns reflect dissimilaritiesin unemployment insurance (UI) systems in a way that convincinglyestablishes the link between economic incentives and job searchbehaviour. Specifically, UI benefits are relatively more generousfor low-income workers in Sweden than in Norway, leading torelatively longer unemployment spells for low-income workersin Sweden. Based on the between-countries variation in replacementratios, we find that the elasticity of the outflow rate frominsured unemployment with respect to the replacement ratio isapproximately one in Norway and 0.5 in Sweden. 相似文献
30.
Feldstein and Horioka (Econ J 90:314–329, 1980) observed that saving and investment move closely together in the major OECD
countries. This finding is a puzzle if national economies are characterized by one sector neoclassical production functions—with
diminishing returns to capital, a high level of savings in a country should create an incentive to export capital. In this
paper, we show that this incentive disappears in the presence of multiple sectors with differing capital intensities. In a
high saving country, national capital can be absorbed domestically without a decline in its marginal product through a shift
in the sectoral composition of national production towards capital intensive sectors. This is nothing but the well-known Rybczynski
effect. We present a modified version of the standard Heckscher–Ohlin (HO) Model to show that very small barriers to capital
mobility are enough to force national savings to stay within the country of origin. We also argue that, while the assumptions
of this model may appear special, they are not unrealistic for the developed countries in the Feldstein Horioka study. Some
historical economic trends are also consistent with the picture presented in this paper. Finally, the paper shows that the
conventional insights from the one sector neoclassical model can be completely overturned in a multi-sector setting when technological
differences are introduced.
相似文献
Ufuk DemirogluEmail: |