全文获取类型
收费全文 | 27653篇 |
免费 | 588篇 |
国内免费 | 2篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 5528篇 |
工业经济 | 2173篇 |
计划管理 | 4640篇 |
经济学 | 6126篇 |
综合类 | 360篇 |
运输经济 | 155篇 |
旅游经济 | 403篇 |
贸易经济 | 4406篇 |
农业经济 | 1382篇 |
经济概况 | 2986篇 |
信息产业经济 | 1篇 |
邮电经济 | 83篇 |
出版年
2020年 | 292篇 |
2019年 | 384篇 |
2018年 | 441篇 |
2017年 | 513篇 |
2016年 | 491篇 |
2015年 | 345篇 |
2014年 | 521篇 |
2013年 | 2585篇 |
2012年 | 724篇 |
2011年 | 798篇 |
2010年 | 681篇 |
2009年 | 810篇 |
2008年 | 673篇 |
2007年 | 735篇 |
2006年 | 650篇 |
2005年 | 542篇 |
2004年 | 527篇 |
2003年 | 564篇 |
2002年 | 564篇 |
2001年 | 538篇 |
2000年 | 598篇 |
1999年 | 487篇 |
1998年 | 522篇 |
1997年 | 529篇 |
1996年 | 504篇 |
1995年 | 483篇 |
1994年 | 489篇 |
1993年 | 470篇 |
1992年 | 545篇 |
1991年 | 538篇 |
1990年 | 438篇 |
1989年 | 362篇 |
1988年 | 374篇 |
1987年 | 390篇 |
1986年 | 419篇 |
1985年 | 583篇 |
1984年 | 589篇 |
1983年 | 534篇 |
1982年 | 519篇 |
1981年 | 546篇 |
1980年 | 482篇 |
1979年 | 489篇 |
1978年 | 385篇 |
1977年 | 310篇 |
1976年 | 275篇 |
1975年 | 309篇 |
1974年 | 227篇 |
1973年 | 251篇 |
1972年 | 183篇 |
1971年 | 172篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 11 毫秒
991.
Curtis R. PriceRoman M. Sheremeta 《Economics Letters》2011,111(3):217-219
We experimentally study overbidding in contests and find that overbidding is significantly higher when subjects are given a large per-experiment endowment rather than when the endowment is given per-period. Risk-aversion and non-monetary utility of winning can partially explain our findings. 相似文献
992.
Rocco R. Huang 《European Economic Review》2007,51(1):161-181
This paper provides evidence supporting Grossman's (Comments on Alan V. Deardorff, Determinants of bilateral trade: Does gravity work in a neoclassical world?. In: Jeffrey A. Frankel (Ed.), The regionalization of the world economy. Chicago: University of Chicago for NBER; 1996) claim that not only transport costs but also unfamiliarity can explain the negative correlation between geographic distances and bilateral trade volumes. A gravity model that controls for as many natural causes of trade as possible reveals that countries high in uncertainty-aversion (based on Hofstede's survey) export disproportionately less to distant countries (with which they are presumably less familiar). More important, this result is mainly driven by differentiated products, not by products with international organized exchanges or with reference prices. For transport costs alone to explain such a trade pattern, one would have to assume that distance-related ad valorem transport costs are higher when a trade route originates from a high uncertainty-aversion country, which is unlikely. This trade pattern is easy to explain, however, if one accepts that geographic distance is a proxy for unfamiliarity and that exporters in high uncertainty-aversion countries are more sensitive to informational ambiguity. A further result is that high uncertainty-aversion countries trade less and thus grow poorer in the long run, which suggests that cultural factors are as important as geographic ones in determining trade openness and prosperity. 相似文献
993.
We introduce the first consistent series of domestic-product and related import price indices at the industry level for the UK, using the data to analyse both domestic and international determinants of UK manufactured product prices. Foreign influences on UK prices in domestic markets are always present, but domestic cost movements dominate. We show that the pass-through of world-price, tariff and exchange rate changes into product prices is partial in general and varies markedly between product categories. Standard tariff and exchange rate theories overstate price responses to global pricing determinants and fail to allow for variation between industrial sectors. Such theories can mislead when used for policy analysis and prediction. 相似文献
994.
We present a tractable, dynamic general equilibrium model of state‐dependent pricing and study the response of output and prices to monetary policy shocks. We find important nonlinearities in these responses. For empirically relevant shocks, this generates substantially different predictions from time‐dependent pricing. We also find a distinct asymmetry with state‐dependent pricing: Prices respond more to positive shocks than they do to negative shocks. This is due to a strategic linkage between firms in the incentive for price adjustment. Our state‐dependent model can account for business cycle asymmetries in output of the magnitude found in empirical studies. 相似文献
995.
Edward E. Schlee 《International Economic Review》2007,48(3):869-899
The welfare change from a price increase–for example, the compensating variation (cv)—is often calculated using the expenditure function from an estimated demand. If there is unobserved preference heterogeneity, then the estimated demand is an average over households with different preferences. And the cv from the mean demand does not generally equal the mean cv. We give conditions ensuring that the cv from the mean demand equals the mean cv, is less than the mean cv, and approximates the mean cv better than the change in consumers' surplus. A necessary condition is that demands become more dispersed as income rises. 相似文献
996.
R. Martínez-Espiñeira 《Environmental and Resource Economics》2007,37(2):335-360
The willingness to pay (WTP) for a coyote conservation program is estimated using a novel payment-vehicle, based on how many
‚problem’ coyotes respondents would be willing to sponsor for a year. This hypothetical scenario mimics an increasingly popular
type of actual market. Data from a phone survey conducted in Prince Edward Island are analyzed using count data models that
consider different processes explaining zero responses and the level of positive responses. This is particularly important
in the case of coyotes, often regarded as an economic bad. Estimates of WTP per coyote per year around $18–$22 and annual
WTP per contributor of about $46–$57 are obtained.
相似文献
997.
In Rome, on 16 March 1978, the Red Brigades kidnapped Aldo Moro. They kept him a prisoner for 55 days, and ultimately killed him. Why did they decide to kill Moro since it appears a posteriori that they did not improve their situation by doing so? Our paper answers this question by building mainly on the model of kidnapping by Selten (A simple game model of kidnapping. In: Henn R, Moeschlin O (eds) Mathematical economics and game theory. Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems, vol. 141. Springer, Berlin, pp 139–156, 1977). We develop an integrated game-theoretic model that reliably captures both the problem of kidnapping for some sort of non-monetary ransom and the problem of assassination of prominent political figures. We embed our model within the historical evidence surrounding the Moro case. We show that, in the Moro case, there is a continuum of equilibria implying the death of the hostage. 相似文献
998.
999.
1000.