首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   252篇
  免费   8篇
财政金融   84篇
工业经济   19篇
计划管理   18篇
经济学   58篇
综合类   1篇
旅游经济   2篇
贸易经济   25篇
农业经济   7篇
经济概况   25篇
水利工程   21篇
  2024年   2篇
  2023年   2篇
  2020年   2篇
  2019年   4篇
  2016年   5篇
  2015年   2篇
  2014年   8篇
  2013年   14篇
  2012年   18篇
  2011年   16篇
  2010年   13篇
  2009年   8篇
  2008年   13篇
  2007年   7篇
  2006年   16篇
  2005年   5篇
  2004年   4篇
  2003年   3篇
  2002年   3篇
  2000年   6篇
  1999年   4篇
  1998年   2篇
  1997年   7篇
  1996年   4篇
  1995年   2篇
  1994年   4篇
  1993年   11篇
  1992年   9篇
  1991年   5篇
  1990年   4篇
  1989年   3篇
  1988年   4篇
  1987年   3篇
  1986年   3篇
  1985年   5篇
  1984年   6篇
  1983年   3篇
  1982年   3篇
  1981年   5篇
  1980年   2篇
  1979年   2篇
  1978年   1篇
  1977年   2篇
  1976年   2篇
  1975年   1篇
  1974年   2篇
  1973年   1篇
  1972年   2篇
  1968年   2篇
  1966年   1篇
排序方式: 共有260条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
151.
There is evidence that attractive looking workers earn more than average looking workers, even after controlling for a variety of individual characteristics. The presence of such beauty premiums may influence the labor supply decisions of attractive workers. For example, if one unit of a product by an attractive worker is more rewarded than that by her less attractive coworker, the attractive worker may put more effort into improving her productivity. We examine this possibility by analyzing panel data for individual female golfers participating in the Ladies Professional Golf Association (LPGA) tour. We found that attractive golfers recorded lower than average scores and earn more prize money than average looking players, even when controlling for player experience and other variables related to their natural talents. This finding is consistent with the notion that physical appearance is associated with individual workers' accumulation of human capital or skills. If the human capital of attractive workers is at least partly an outcome of favoritism toward beauty, then the premium estimates obtained by previous studies may have been downwardly biased. (JEL J3, J7, L8)  相似文献   
152.
This paper introduces an endogenously‐determined fertility rate into a Romer‐type endogenous growth model and, accordingly, investigates the effects on fertility, economic growth and social welfare of a revenue‐neutral tax reform that involves switching from an income tax to a consumption tax. We show that, in a departure from the existing literature, tax reform could be harmful, rather than favourable, to both growth and welfare, due to an endogenous fertility rate. We also conduct a simple numerical analysis to investigate under what conditions the negative effect on growth and welfare occurs.  相似文献   
153.
Total factor productivity growth of the five ASEAN founding members is estimated by decomposing total factor productivity growth into technical efficiency and technological progress. By using the stochastic frontier model with individual‐specific temporal pattern of technical efficiency for the period of 1981–2003, the present paper identifies the unique temporal pattern of productivity changes in each country, to analyze the relationship between country characteristics and the inherent efficiency and productivity changes. The empirical results indicate that over the study period, growth in Singapore and Malaysia was largely driven by both technological progress and input accumulation, whereas growth in Thailand was induced by an improvement in technical efficiency and through input accumulation.  相似文献   
154.
At the center of the issues set out in the 1997 WTO Agreement on Basic Telecommunication Services was the creation of separate telecom regulatory agencies. Using the Cox proportional hazards model, this study examines how a country's socioeconomic factors affect the country's incentive to reorganize its regulatory structure and create a separate telecom regulatory agency. The main empirical findings suggest that a country's incentive to institute a separate telecom regulatory body is greater when its telecom sector performance is relatively poor and its political environment is more competitive with few institutional barriers. (JEL L52, L96 )  相似文献   
155.
156.
热泡数值研究   总被引:3,自引:2,他引:1  
本文对二维热泡的演化过程进行数值研究,所采用的湍流封闭模式为双方程k-ε方程。数值结果表明:无量纲时间大于10后,流动与混合特性均符合自相似关系;热泡流场可分两区。混合区中示踪剂浓度场呈双峰肾形、湍流脉动强烈、旋流含一对涡眼,而外区示踪剂浓度为零、流动有势且符合偶极子模型;热泡流的附加等效质量系数近乎1,自相似阶段热泡的宽高比约为1.45。所得热泡扩展率和混合率亦与实验数据相符。  相似文献   
157.
158.
Abstract. Option market activity increases by more than 10 percent in the four days before quarterly earnings announcements. We show that the direction of this preannouncement trading foreshadows subsequent earnings news. Specifically, we find option traders initiate a greater proportion of long (short) positions immediately before “good” (“bad”) earnings news. Midquote returns to active-side option trades are positive during nonannouncement periods and are significantly higher immediately prior to earnings announcements. Bid-ask spreads for options widen during the announcement period, but traders do not gravitate toward high delta contracts. Collectively, the evidence shows option traders participate generally in price discovery (the incorporation of private information in price), and more specifically in the dissemination of earnings news.  相似文献   
159.
We examine how corporate social media affects the capital market consequences of firms’ disclosure in the context of consumer product recalls. Product recalls constitute a “product crisis” exposing the firm to reputational damage, loss of future sales, and legal liability. During such a crisis it is crucial for the firm to quickly and directly communicate its intended message to a wide network of stakeholders, which, in turn, renders corporate social media a potentially useful channel of disclosure. While we document that corporate social media, on average, attenuates the negative price reaction to recall announcements, the attenuation benefits of corporate social media vary with the level of control the firm has over its social media content. In particular, with the arrival of Facebook and Twitter, firms relinquished complete control over their social media content, and the attenuation benefits of corporate social media, while still significant, lessened. Detailed Twitter analysis confirms that the moderating effect of social media varies with the level of firm involvement and with the amount of control exerted by other users: the negative price reaction to a recall is attenuated by the frequency of tweets by the firm, while exacerbated by the frequency of tweets by other users.  相似文献   
160.
This paper re‐examines the stationarity of inflation rates in 19 Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development countries with the use of cross‐sectional information. We employ the panel unit‐root tests that allow for cross‐sectional dependency and the covariate point optimal test. These tests have high power in common due to the exploitation of cross‐sectional information, and they can assist mutually to draw a concrete conclusion on inflation dynamics for all series in the panel. Our empirical results show that allowing for cross‐sectional dependency rejects the null hypothesis that all series in the panel have a unit root, implying that there is at least one stationary series in the panel. With the help of the results of the covariate test, we can distinguish the panel into a group of stationary and a group of non‐stationary series. For robustness, the two groups of series are re‐confirmed by the panel tests. Our results reveal evidence of mean reversion in inflation for 15 of 19 countries, which is significantly stronger as compared to that obtained by the state‐of‐the‐art univariate unit‐root tests.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号