全文获取类型
收费全文 | 4537篇 |
免费 | 277篇 |
国内免费 | 1篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 1237篇 |
工业经济 | 40篇 |
计划管理 | 323篇 |
经济学 | 1924篇 |
综合类 | 15篇 |
旅游经济 | 7篇 |
贸易经济 | 427篇 |
农业经济 | 135篇 |
经济概况 | 707篇 |
出版年
2024年 | 1篇 |
2023年 | 22篇 |
2022年 | 18篇 |
2021年 | 38篇 |
2020年 | 197篇 |
2019年 | 206篇 |
2018年 | 110篇 |
2017年 | 142篇 |
2016年 | 98篇 |
2015年 | 148篇 |
2014年 | 325篇 |
2013年 | 321篇 |
2012年 | 377篇 |
2011年 | 599篇 |
2010年 | 399篇 |
2009年 | 355篇 |
2008年 | 258篇 |
2007年 | 286篇 |
2006年 | 240篇 |
2005年 | 197篇 |
2004年 | 71篇 |
2003年 | 57篇 |
2002年 | 61篇 |
2001年 | 33篇 |
2000年 | 27篇 |
1999年 | 32篇 |
1998年 | 33篇 |
1997年 | 36篇 |
1996年 | 41篇 |
1995年 | 21篇 |
1994年 | 31篇 |
1993年 | 3篇 |
1992年 | 1篇 |
1990年 | 1篇 |
1985年 | 4篇 |
1984年 | 6篇 |
1983年 | 3篇 |
1982年 | 5篇 |
1980年 | 7篇 |
1979年 | 2篇 |
1977年 | 3篇 |
排序方式: 共有4815条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
51.
We derive fundamental theory for measuring monetary service flows aggregated over countries within a multicountry area. We develop three increasingly restrictive approaches: (1) the heterogeneous agents approach, (2) the multilateral representative agent approach, and (3) the unilateral representative agent approach. These results are being used by the European Central Bank in construction of its Divisia monetary aggregates database, with convergence from the most general to the more restrictive approaches expected as economic convergence within the area proceeds. Our theory permits monitoring the effects of policy over a multicountry area, while also monitoring the distribution effects of policy among the countries. 相似文献
52.
Chad P. Bown 《Asian Economic Policy Review》2022,17(1):114-135
Early in the COVID-19 pandemic, a global shortage of hospital gowns, gloves, surgical masks, and respirators caused policymakers globally to panic. China increased imports and decreased exports of this personal protective equipment, removing supplies from world markets. Shortages led to European Union and US export controls as well as other extraordinary policy actions, including a US effort to reserve supplies manufactured in China by a US-headquartered multinational. By April 2020, China's exports had mostly resumed, and over the rest of the year its export volumes surged. But China's export prices also skyrocketed and remained elevated through 2020, reflecting severe and continued shortages. This paper explores these and other government actions, such as US trade war tariffs and US industrial policy in the form of over $1 billion of subsidies to build out its domestic personal protective equipment supply chain, as well as potential lessons for future pandemic preparedness and international policy cooperation. 相似文献
53.
Christian Dustmann 《European Economic Review》2003,47(2):353-369
In simple static models, migration increases with the wage differential between host- and home-country. In a dynamic framework, and if migrations are temporary, the size of the migrant population in the host country depends also on the migration duration. This paper analyses optimal migration durations in a model which rationalises the decision of the migrant to return to his home country, despite persistently higher wages in the host country. The analysis shows that, if migrations are temporary, the optimal migration duration may decrease if the wage differential grows larger. Using micro data for Germany, the second part of the paper provides empirical evidence which is compatible with this hypothesis. 相似文献
54.
The paper develops a North–Middle–South model to formulate a middle economy that plays catch-up via imitative R&D to acquire newer technologies from a higher-wage innovative forerunner, while playing “reverse catch-up” via outbound FDI to transfer older technologies to a lower-wage follower. A critical policy dilemma facing the middle economy is how to balance its R&D-driven technology inflows against its FDI-driven technology outflows. Numerical simulations are used for dynamic welfare analysis. This paper finds that tightening FDI permits the middle economy to keep a lower saving rate without weakening its ability to acquire newer technologies in the long run. 相似文献
55.
Lai Yew Wah 《International economic journal》2013,27(3):337-352
For the past four decades (1961-2000), the Malaysian economy grew at an impressive average rate of 6.8% per annum. The rapid growth has been attributed, in part, to the tremendous success in the export-oriented industrialization policy. Several empirical studies on export-led growth for Malaysia have, however, led to inconclusive and mixed results. This may be due to the exclusion of domestic demand in the bivariate or multivariate models used in the studies. This study re-examines the role of domestic demand in economic growth in Malaysia. Using a three-variable cointegration analysis, the study shows that there exist short run bilateral causalities among the three variables, which implies that both the export-led growth and domestic demand-generated growth hypotheses are at least valid in the short run. On the other hand, the results are not supportive of the export-led growth hypothesis in the long run. Instead, the highly significant positive impact of domestic expenditure on economic growth implies that use of domestic demand as the catalyst for growth is appropriate. 相似文献
56.
Richard Pomfret 《Asian Economic Policy Review》2013,8(1):25-41
Since Vietnam, Lao People's Democratic Republic (PDR), Myanmar, and Cambodia joined the Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) in the 1990s, concerns have been raised over a Development Divide. The real division is between ASEAN members participating in the integrated East Asian economy and those that do not. The older ASEAN members have become more efficient traders, and Cambodia, Laos, Myanmar, and Vietnam must reform faster if they are to catch up. Cambodia, Lao PDR, and Myanmar are not meeting the challenge, but Vietnam may be leaving the laggards, and the Philippines is lagging the leaders. The challenge is how to avoid a two‐tier ASEAN with fast‐growing modern economies coexisting besides inward‐looking poor countries. 相似文献
57.
58.
59.
This paper estimates the effect of the decision to import intermediate goods and capital equipment on Total Factor Productivity (TFP) at the firm level on a panel of Spanish firms (1991–2002). We use two alternative approaches. In the first, we estimate TFP and apply a diff‐in‐diff estimator with a control group constructed by propensity‐score matching. In the second, direct method, we estimate TFP with imported inputs as a state variable in one stage. Both approaches show that the effect of a firm's decision to source intermediates and capital equipment abroad on its TFP depends critically on its capacity to absorb technology, measured by the proportion of skilled labour. 相似文献
60.
Chang Hong 《The Canadian journal of economics》2013,46(4):1295-1316
We analyze China's tariff rates at WTO accession using a political economy approach. A model drawing on Branstetter and Feenstra ( 2002 ) is used to derive an optimal tariff rate for each industry. The model predicts that a government would set a high tariff rate if an industry is of large state‐owned enterprise (SOE) share, multinational share, or small foreign import share. From the model we reveal the Chinese government's preference towards different interest groups under the binding tariff constraint from the WTO commitments. The estimated structural parameters imply that the political weights on both the SOE profits and consumer income diminish with the economic opening. More important, the government still favours SOEs over consumer income. Our findings are consistent with the special features of China's economy. 相似文献