首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   381篇
  免费   11篇
  国内免费   1篇
财政金融   23篇
工业经济   21篇
计划管理   56篇
经济学   78篇
综合类   60篇
运输经济   3篇
旅游经济   20篇
贸易经济   74篇
农业经济   18篇
经济概况   40篇
  2025年   4篇
  2024年   5篇
  2023年   5篇
  2022年   6篇
  2021年   10篇
  2020年   16篇
  2019年   10篇
  2018年   11篇
  2017年   17篇
  2016年   14篇
  2015年   9篇
  2014年   14篇
  2013年   44篇
  2012年   37篇
  2011年   32篇
  2010年   25篇
  2009年   25篇
  2008年   19篇
  2007年   22篇
  2006年   18篇
  2005年   21篇
  2004年   6篇
  2003年   6篇
  2002年   3篇
  2001年   2篇
  2000年   2篇
  1999年   3篇
  1998年   1篇
  1997年   4篇
  1994年   1篇
  1985年   1篇
排序方式: 共有393条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
91.
西方经济学与马克思主义经济学作为两种不同的经济学范式,在对经济行为主体人性假设前提问题上迥然有异.文章对马克思主义经济学与西方经济学的人性假设进行了比较分析,认为\"社会人\"与\"经济人\"人性的不同假设成为两大范式的分水岭,这涉及人性与人的本质问题的认识,要全面地、联系地、发展地来考虑人性假设问题,提出一个具有更强解释力的经济学人性假定,演绎出一个能反映个人与社会现实互动关系的理论框架,促进经济学的发展.  相似文献   
92.
    
The US national innovation system has a dual structure: part suited to rapid innovation, and part stubbornly resistant to change. The complex, established ‘Legacy sectors’ that resist change, particularly disruptive innovation, share common features that obstruct the market launch of innovations, over and above the ‘valley of death’ and other obstacles that have been the traditional focus of innovation policy. Innovations in Legacy sectors must penetrate a well-established and well-defended technological/economic/political/social paradigm that favours existing technology, characterised by (1) ‘perverse’ subsidies and price structures that create a mismatch between the incentives of producers and broader social goals, such as environmental sustainability, public health and safety, and geopolitical security; (2) established infrastructure and institutional architecture that imposes regulatory hurdles or other disadvantages to new entrants (3) market imperfections beyond those faced by other innovations: network economies, lumpiness, economies of scale, split incentives, needs for collective action, and transaction costs (4) politically powerful vested interests, reinforced by public support, that defend the paradigm and resist innovations that threaten their business models (5) public habits and expectations attuned to existing technology and (6) an established knowledge and human resources structure adapted to its needs. Beyond these obstacles, more socially desirable technologies that are driven by environmental or other non-market considerations must overcome the lack of agreed replacement standards against which putative alternatives can be judged. We have developed a new, integrative analytic framework for categorising the obstacles to market launch faced by Legacy sectors, and earlier applied this method to energy, health delivery, the long-distance electric grid, building, and air transport. In energy especially, the requirement for innovation is sufficiently urgent that large-scale domestic and collaborative international research should take place even at the cost of possible competitive disadvantage and even if it is some time before the USA adopts carbon charges and thereby puts pressure on the prevailing paradigm of fossil fuel use. We now extend this method to sustainable agriculture. American paradigms in agriculture and in energy are exported worldwide, delaying the development and spread of needed innovations that are not consistent with them. Foreign manufacturers wishing to enter US markets must suit their products in these sectors to American paradigms, while American exports of technology may be insufficiently cost conscious or respectful of environmental sustainability. Developing countries are technology takers and suffer from asymmetric innovative capability. They need to choose sources of technology best suited to their situation. India and China constitute new competitive threats, but also represent ‘innovative developing countries’ that have large domestic markets in which they are launching innovations aimed at their lower income populations.  相似文献   
93.
    
In recent political-economic theories of ‘nature’, Mill and Marx/Engels form important reference points. Ecological economists see Mill's ‘stationary state’ as seminal, while Marxists have ‘brought capitalism back in’ to debates on growth and climate change, sparking a Marxological renaissance that has overturned our understanding of Marx/Engels' opus. This article explores aspects of Mill's and Marx/Engels' work and contemporary reception. It identifies a resemblance between their historical dialectics. Marx's communism is driven by logics of ‘agency’ and ‘structure’ (including the ‘tendency of profit rates to fall’). In Mill's dialectic a ‘thesis’, material progress, calls forth its ‘antithesis’, diminishing returns. The inevitable ‘Aufhebung’ is a stationary state of wealth and population; Mill mentions countervailing tendencies but fails to consider their capacity to postpone utopia's arrival. Today, Mill's schema lives on in ecological economics, shorn of determinism but with its market advocacy intact. It appears to contrast with the ‘productive forces expansion’ espoused by Marx/Engels. They stand accused of ‘Promethean arrogance’, ignoring ‘natural limits’ and ‘gambling on abundance’. But I find these criticisms to be ill-judged, and propose an alternative reading, arguing that their work contains a critique of the ‘growth paradigm’, and that their ‘cornucopian’ ends do not sanction ‘Promethean’ means.  相似文献   
94.
产业网络成长范式研究:基于创新与互补性资产视角   总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1  
施氏产业微笑曲线认为在成熟的产业经济中,能给产业带来高附加值的关键环节是研发设计和销售品牌环节。然而,随着产业价值链的分解,各个环节形成了大量相对独立厂商,那么原来仅仅依靠技术创新的成长范式已经远远不能够适应产业经济形势的发展,所产生的附加值也没有原来那么高。那么,产业经济需要新的成长发展范式,即企业之间根据不确定性组建产业网络,依靠互补性资产和持续创新实现产业经济的永续发展。  相似文献   
95.
Typical psychometric paradigm factors appear to have greater explanatory power for individual participants than previously envisaged. It is possible to acquire interpretable information about single participants using two factors (catastrophic potential and social and personal exposure) from aggregated participant‐focused data. Our results suggest that the classical psychometric model originated by Fischhoff and Slovic in the early 1980s to explain differences among hazards may also be capable of accounting for differences among participants. While socio‐demographic conditions on their own do not have substantial explanatory power, they are statistically significant and appear to dictate the position of participants within the factor space obtained using a participant‐focused analysis. One of the principal criticisms of the psychometric paradigm has been its lack of interpretability when using disaggregated data, but incorporating socio‐demographic variables overcomes this limitation.  相似文献   
96.
The paper analyzes the role of agency driven takeover activity. The analysis shows that takeovers can play an important role in reducing agency costs even though the gains from the corporate restructuring that follows the takeovers are zero, which counters existing models of agency driven takeover activity. The model can therefore form the basis for deriving empirical predictions which discriminate between the agency paradigm and the corporate restructuring paradigm of takeover activity. Negative post-merger performance (Agrawal et al., 1992), which is inconsistent with corporate restructuring is consistent with this model, and that takeover targets' investment levels are below or at the average (Servaes 1994), which is inconsistent with the free cash flow theory is also consistent with this model.  相似文献   
97.
人力资本主导范式下的两权融合与分离   总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1  
所有权与经营权如何配置是影响和决定企业核心竞争力的基础制度问题,两权配置是否科学合理将从根本上关系着企业的兴衰成败。从整体看,企业所有权与经营权的制度安排有两种范式:一是物质资本主导下的传统制度范式;二是由人力资本所主导的新生制度范式。人力资本主导范式企业的两权配置需要实行人合物离模式,具体为:需要以人力资本所有权与经营权的完全融合为配置基础,在此基础上由人力资本主导的极致分离物质资本所有权与经营权的结合。人合物离模式集成了两权分离与两权融合两种配置模式的优势,将适应新经济的要求,其精髓在于该模式实现了以人为本与以利为本的有机结合,是现代企业制度发展的主流终极配置模式。  相似文献   
98.
Fritjof Capra 《Futures》1985,17(5):475-478
In science, the framework of systems theory—especially as developed over the past two decades—seems to be the ideal framework to express the emerging ecological paradigm. This article addresses the question: what is systems thinking—and more generally, holistic or ecological thinking—in modern science? The author identifies three key aspects of systems thinking that are characteristic in all the sciences. In presenting these aspects, the transition from the old to the new paradigm for each aspect is emphasized.  相似文献   
99.
    
While systematic literature reviews (SLRs) have contributed substantially to developing knowledge in fields such as medicine, they have made limited contributions to developing knowledge in the supply chain management domain. This is due to the ontological and epistemological idiosyncrasies of research in supply chain management, which need to be accounted for when retrieving, selecting, and synthesizing studies in an SLR. Therefore, we propose a new paradigm for SLRs in the supply chain domain that is based on both best practice and the unique attributes of doing supply chain management research. This approach involves exploring existing studies with attention to theoretical boundaries, units of analysis, sources of data, study contexts, and definitions and the operationalization of constructs, as well as research methods, with the goal of refining or revising existing theory. This new paradigm will push supply chain management research to the frontier of current methodological standards and build a foundation for improving the contribution of future SLRs in the supply chain and adjacent management disciplines.  相似文献   
100.
Institutions and the OLI paradigm of the multinational enterprise   总被引:2,自引:2,他引:2  
The prevailing ownership-based theories of the firm are increasingly being challenged by new forms of organising, as exemplified by the Asian network multinational enterprise (MNE). We believe that an institutional approach, that tries to bridge both the macro and micro levels of analysis, and that encompasses both formal and informal institutions, offers a promising way to advance our understanding of the different forms of the contemporary MNE. This paper introduces a theoretical framework that draws substantially on the work of Douglass North, and examines how an institutional dimension can be incorporated into the three components of the OLI paradigm.
Sarianna M. Lundan (Corresponding author)Email:

John H. Dunning   is Emeritus Professor of International Business at the University of Reading, UK and at Rutgers University, US. He is an ex-president of both the Academy of International Business, and the International Trade and Finance Association. He has written or edited 48 books and more than 250 articles in professional journals. Sarianna M. Lundan   is Associate Professor of International Business Strategy at the University of Maastricht in the Netherlands and Research Fellow at ETLA, the Research Institute of the Finnish Economy in Helsinki. She is the co-author with John Dunning of the second edition of Multinational Enterprises and the Global Economy, a major reference work in the field of International Business.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号