全文获取类型
收费全文 | 501篇 |
免费 | 23篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 55篇 |
工业经济 | 26篇 |
计划管理 | 83篇 |
经济学 | 164篇 |
综合类 | 12篇 |
运输经济 | 11篇 |
旅游经济 | 15篇 |
贸易经济 | 86篇 |
农业经济 | 26篇 |
经济概况 | 46篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 7篇 |
2022年 | 17篇 |
2021年 | 21篇 |
2020年 | 32篇 |
2019年 | 28篇 |
2018年 | 43篇 |
2017年 | 37篇 |
2016年 | 28篇 |
2015年 | 16篇 |
2014年 | 40篇 |
2013年 | 43篇 |
2012年 | 28篇 |
2011年 | 41篇 |
2010年 | 26篇 |
2009年 | 19篇 |
2008年 | 21篇 |
2007年 | 20篇 |
2006年 | 20篇 |
2005年 | 14篇 |
2004年 | 8篇 |
2003年 | 4篇 |
2002年 | 4篇 |
2001年 | 1篇 |
2000年 | 2篇 |
1995年 | 1篇 |
1992年 | 1篇 |
1984年 | 2篇 |
排序方式: 共有524条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
121.
Whatever the final charge on the UK for leaving the EU, the money itself is relatively marginal to the former's public finances. However, this charge is politically sensitive and financially aggravating during one of the longest periods of fiscal austerity in the UK's history. The ways in which leaving is conceptualized have implications for any continuing financial obligations that must be managed within the context of fiscal austerity and political uncertainty. Yet, leaving the EU is a unique transaction: it is not analogous, for example, to a divorce settlement, the leaving of a club, the termination of a commercial contract, the leaving of a treaty-based international organization, or secession from a state. Analyzing the formulation of the charge in terms of the four modes of government accounting—financial reporting, statistical accounting, budgeting, and fiscal sustainability projections—enhances its fiscal transparency. It evidences not only the weakness and inconsistency of the UK's negotiating position but also the dominance in EU thinking of the short-term budgetary calculations of the 2014–20 Multiannual Financial Framework over its long-term sustainability without a large net contributor. The final amount paid by the UK will depend on the resolution of competing perspectives as well as on liabilities and contingent liabilities associated with the increasingly complex EU financial architecture. 相似文献
122.
知识协同行为和非知识协同行为是知识管理领域新的研究主题,探讨其内在影响机理具有重要意义。通过数据调查,利用结构方程模型深入分析和探讨了环境扰动对知识协同行为和非知识协同行为的影响机理。实证研究表明:环境扰动正向影响非知识协同行为的产生,而环境扰动对知识协同行为的影响并不显著;良性非知识协同行为与企业创新绩效显著正相关,而恶性非知识协同行为对企业创新绩效有一定反向影响,知识协同行为对组织创新绩效有着显著正向影响;良性非知识协同行为对知识协同行为有较强的正向影响,而恶性非知识协同行为反向影响良性非知识协同行为的产生,这意味着恶性非知识协同行为可以通过良性非知识协同行为的中介效应对知识协同行为、创新绩效起反向作用。 相似文献
123.
124.
罗小芳 《中南财经政法大学学报》2012,(2):9-14,142
由于我国社会习俗、文化、价值观等非正式约束与正式约束的不匹配,导致《劳动合同法》的实施效果不尽如人意,这些非正式约束的限制主要表现在:关系经济降低了正式劳动合约的作用;集体主义制约了正式契约关系的拓展;等级制不利于建立平等的劳动契约关系;人治不利于劳动契约按法律的手段有效实施。正式制度只有在与非正式制度相容的情况下才能发挥作用,我国劳动关系契约化中正式约束与非正式约束不相适应会带来一些问题,主要表现在:它将影响我国社会从身份到契约的进程;影响我国《劳动合同法》的实施及其效果;它使劳动合同的作用难以发挥。 相似文献
125.
通过对改革开放后第一家私人钱庄兴衰的史实进行重新考察和审视,本文经研究发现,尽管权力当局把资金自由交易权界定给了监管部门,但因监管成本和信息成本过高而无法保障该产权,个人会通过参与各类非正规金融活动来攫取一部分置于公共领域的权利。本文还基于交易费用理论解释了我国金融市场禁人政策出现松动的原因,也即维持扭曲型二元金融制度的成本以及严禁农村非正规金融活动的费用都越来越高,而且国内的经济形势也提出了放松监管的要求,在这些因素的作用下监管部门执行原有金融抑制政策的力度终于降低了。 相似文献
126.
研究生学术水平受正式制度约束,也受包括校园文化、学术道德规范和指导模式等非正式制度影响。经调查表明,校风、教风和学风以及学科建设氛围对研究生学术认同度的提高、学术理想的树立产生间接而深远的影响。指导模式直接影响研究生学术努力行为,是研究生提高学术水平的重要途径。研究生学术水平评价应以建立学术认同和遵守学术道德规范为前提,否则将会导致研究生学术行为的异化。 相似文献
127.
While many studies of the motivations behind the corporate social responsibility reporting (CSRR) practices of large corporations have been reported internationally, few have focussed on multinational corporation (MNC) subsidiaries. Most importantly, we still do not know how host country institutional norms, or parent corporation policies, influence MNC subsidiaries embarking upon CSRR. By integrating legitimacy theory (LT) and neo-institutional theory (NIT) explanations, this paper offers a theoretical framework for investigating the CSRR practices of MNC subsidiaries in general, and provides empirical evidence on the nature and motivations of subsidiaries’ CSRR practices in Bangladesh, a developing country. Employing a case study method and using qualitative data, the study finds that CSRR practice in Bangladeshi MNC subsidiaries is limited, consisting mainly of employee information. This observation mirrors the overall CSRR trend in Bangladesh. A desire for internal legitimacy emerges as the primary motivation for CSRR practice in MNC subsidiaries. In particular, the external host country environment of the Bangladeshi subsidiaries seems to be a major limitation in the development of CSRR. 相似文献
128.
《Food Policy》2013
Cameroon is the first trading partner of the Economic and Monetary Community of Central Africa (CEMAC) countries. Despite belonging to the same sub-regional organization, the formal trade ties between Cameroon and its neighbours have been hampered by a combination of factors that have spurred the growth of informal (unrecorded) trade. Interest in cross-border trade of agricultural and horticultural commodities between Cameroon and its neighbours has been overwhelming, but knowledge of its magnitude, determinants, and consequences remains inadequate, leading not only to undervaluation of figures in the national accounts, but also inhibiting formulation of appropriate policies and strategies to exploit its potential impact, particularly on food security. Using a monitoring method of cross-border flows of informal trade, the study aims to estimate the volume/value of unrecorded cross-border trade between Cameroon and its CEMAC’s neighbours and compare it with the recorded (official figures) trade. The results indicate that in 2008 a volume of just over 155 000 tons of agricultural and horticultural commodities has been shipped from Cameroon to its neighbours in the CEMAC for an estimated value of almost 38 billion CFA francs and representing 0.4% of GDP in Cameroon. The comparison in relative terms shows that informal or unrecorded trade represents 96% of the official and mainly includes agricultural and horticultural commodities. 相似文献
129.
Benito Arruada 《Journal of Comparative Economics》2007,35(4):729-747
Over recent years, both governments and international aid organizations have been devoting large amounts of resources to “simplifying” the procedures for setting up and formalizing firms. Many of these actions have focused on reducing the initial costs of setting up the firm, disregarding the more important role of business registers as a source of reliable information for judges, government departments and, above all, other firms. This reliable information is essential for reducing transaction costs in future dealings with all sorts of economic agents, both public and private. The priorities of reform policies should therefore be thoroughly reviewed, stressing the value of the legal institutions rather than trivializing them as is often the case. Journal of Comparative Economics 35 (4) (2007) 729–747. 相似文献
130.
Martin Kloyer 《Managerial and Decision Economics》2011,32(7):457-468
Because of increasing technological complexity of new products, the manufacturers of final products more often seek access to external sources of knowledge at the early, market‐distant stages of innovation processes. However, they are confronted with a specifically high danger of moral hazard. Traditional management instruments fail to control that danger mainly for two reasons. First, the supplier activities are not transparent. Second, market‐distant R&D results are credence goods whose quality cannot be evaluated, not even ex post. It is the theory of incomplete contracts that solves the problem by allocating the so‐called control rights to the supplier. These rights primarily regulate the assignment of the intellectual property rights, the control of the R&D process, and the marketing of the final products that are based on the delivered R&D results. To date, we do not have any empirical evidence about the relative effectiveness of these control rights. Moreover, studies on incomplete contracts in R&D alliances only focused on the collaboration between biotechnology and pharmaceutical firms. Our study fills these gaps. On the basis of a sample of French and German R&D suppliers, we find that only enforceable intellectual property rights assigned to the supplier effectively control moral hazard. Copyright © 2011 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. 相似文献