全文获取类型
收费全文 | 839篇 |
免费 | 15篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 69篇 |
工业经济 | 22篇 |
计划管理 | 101篇 |
经济学 | 322篇 |
综合类 | 16篇 |
运输经济 | 23篇 |
旅游经济 | 26篇 |
贸易经济 | 128篇 |
农业经济 | 111篇 |
经济概况 | 35篇 |
信息产业经济 | 1篇 |
出版年
2025年 | 1篇 |
2024年 | 13篇 |
2023年 | 25篇 |
2022年 | 5篇 |
2021年 | 20篇 |
2020年 | 43篇 |
2019年 | 40篇 |
2018年 | 39篇 |
2017年 | 58篇 |
2016年 | 54篇 |
2015年 | 37篇 |
2014年 | 50篇 |
2013年 | 113篇 |
2012年 | 41篇 |
2011年 | 27篇 |
2010年 | 11篇 |
2009年 | 46篇 |
2008年 | 44篇 |
2007年 | 29篇 |
2006年 | 27篇 |
2005年 | 26篇 |
2004年 | 21篇 |
2003年 | 20篇 |
2002年 | 17篇 |
2001年 | 11篇 |
2000年 | 11篇 |
1999年 | 7篇 |
1998年 | 4篇 |
1997年 | 2篇 |
1996年 | 3篇 |
1995年 | 3篇 |
1994年 | 2篇 |
1993年 | 1篇 |
1992年 | 1篇 |
1986年 | 1篇 |
1984年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有854条查询结果,搜索用时 18 毫秒
81.
Agricultural production is subject to risk and the attitudes of producers toward risk will influence input choices insofar as these affect production risk. Risk attitudes in turn may be affected by certain socioeconomic characteristics of producers. Using 2004 survey data from a cross‐section of 130 Spanish rice farms, we estimate risk‐aversion coefficients of farmers and investigate the influence of a series of socioeconomic variables on their risk attitudes. Our results show that farmers exhibit risk‐averse behavior and that risk attitudes are related to a series of socioeconomic characteristics. In particular, the belief that the farm will continue after the producer retires is found to increase the degree of risk aversion, while age is found to have nonlinear effects on risk aversion. Off‐farm income, especially from nonagricultural activities, is found to reduce risk aversion. Neither the educational level of the producer nor the presence of dependents on the household is found to have an effect on risk preferences. Regarding the production technology, we find that land, labor, and fitosanitary products are risk‐reducing inputs, whereas capital, seeds, and fertilizer all increase risk. 相似文献
82.
Kai A. Konrad 《International Tax and Public Finance》2008,15(4):395-414
If countries anticipate international Bertrand competition in tax rates, they may expend effort that makes some of their taxpayers
less mobile or increases the mobility of taxpayers elsewhere. Piecemeal evidence on what activities countries use is provided.
Such activities are analyzed that interact with Bertrand tax competition if the size of the groups of loyal and nonloyal citizens
or investors is endogenous. Further, the implications of tax harmonization and minimum taxes for these types of nonprice competition
are considered. Home attachment reduces the intensity of tax competition, but generates a strategic disadvantage for the country
that invests much in such home attachment. Harmonization of taxes and high minimum taxes can intensify countries’ investment
in home attachment.
相似文献
83.
This paper reports our experiences with the application of a number of alternative approaches to a study of women's economic circumstances and quality of life in a typical western city. The important work of, especially, Martha Nussbaum on the capabilities approach to evaluations of “quality of life” has highlighted pitfalls associated with the use of a narrow informational base in studies of women's lives and has emphasized the value of qualitative methods in these evaluations. However, to date, most discussions of the relevance of plural approaches to studies of women's lives have been conducted in the context of developing countries. This paper contributes a practical, current example of the relevance of such approaches to assessments of the lives of women in western countries as well. The research findings reported in the paper also cast further light on the importance of several, related themes in the literature on the capabilities approach, namely the importance of understanding how women's aspirations and expectations change with their economic and social experiences; and the importance of appreciating the social uses of language and how this affects the way in which women describe their lives. 相似文献
84.
85.
Preference Structures, Property Rights, and Paired Comparisons 总被引:2,自引:0,他引:2
Michael Lockwood 《Environmental and Resource Economics》1999,13(1):107-122
The method of paired comparisons was used to determine the structure of survey participants' value expressions for Australian native forests. The same participants were also surveyed using the contingent valuation method (CVM). Data from the paired comparisons were used to construct preference maps which enabled identification of participants whose value expressions were structurally incompatible with economic welfare theory – in particular, those participants who expressed their values according to lexicographic preferences. For some of these participants, CVM results did not provide appropriate measures of WTP. The surveys also demonstrated the importance of allowing participants' own views on property rights to dictate the valuation context offered. 相似文献
86.
James SchummerRakesh V. Vohra 《Journal of Economic Theory》2002,104(2):405-428
We consider rules that choose a location on a graph (e.g. a road network) based on agents' single-peaked preferences. First, we characterize the class of strategy-proof, onto rules when the graph is a tree. Such a rule is based on a collection of generalized median voter rules (Moulin, 1980) satisfying a consistency condition. Second, we characterize such rules for graphs containing cycles. We show that while such a rule is not necessarily dictatorial, the existence of a cycle grants some agent an amount of decisive power, unlike the case of trees. Rules for this case can be described in terms of a subclass of such rules for trees. Journal of Economic Literature Classification Numbers: C72, D78. 相似文献
87.
Ken BinmoreJohn McCarthy Giovanni PontiLarry Samuelson Avner Shaked 《Journal of Economic Theory》2002,104(1):48-88
This paper reports experiments with one-stage and two-stage alternating-offers bargaining games. Payoff-interdependent preferences have been suggested as an explanation for experimental results that are commonly inconsistent with players' maximizing their monetary payoffs and performing backward induction calculations. We examine whether, given payoff-interdependent preferences, players respect backward induction. To do this, we break backward induction into its components, subgame consistency and truncation consistency. We examine each by comparing the outcomes of two-stage bargaining games with one-stage games with varying rejection payoffs. We find and characterize systematic violations of both subgame and truncation consistency. Journal of Economic Literature Classification Numbers: C70, C78. 相似文献
88.
We compare the consistency of choices in two methods used to elicit risk preferences on an aggregate as well as on an individual level. We ask subjects to choose twice from a list of nine decisions between two lotteries, as introduced by Holt and Laury 2002, 2005 ) alternating with nine decisions using the budget approach introduced by Andreoni and Harbaugh ( 2009 ). We find that, while on an aggregate (subject pool) level the results are consistent, on an individual (within‐subject) level, behaviour is far from consistent. Within each method as well as across methods we observe low (simple and rank) correlations. 相似文献
89.
Using Danish survey data from a choice experiment, parental preferences for class-size reduction are estimated. While parents with children in large classes are willing to pay for class-size reduction, parents with children in small classes are reluctant and even express negative utility for further class-size reduction. We interpret this as parents balancing the risk of ‘Lazearian’ interrupters and the benefits of educational and social peers when forming their preferences for class size. 相似文献
90.
According to intuition and theories of diffusion, consumer preferences develop along with technological change. However, most economic models designed for policy simulation unrealistically assume static preferences. To improve the behavioral realism of an energy–economy policy model, this study investigates the “neighbor effect,” where a new technology becomes more desirable as its adoption becomes more widespread in the market. We measure this effect as a change in aggregated willingness to pay under different levels of technology penetration. Focusing on hybrid-electric vehicles (HEVs), an online survey experiment collected stated preference (SP) data from 535 Canadian and 408 Californian vehicle owners under different hypothetical market conditions.Revealed preference (RP) data was collected from the same respondents by eliciting the year, make and model of recent vehicle purchases from regions with different degrees of HEV popularity: Canada with 0.17% new market share, and California with 3.0% new market share. We compare choice models estimated from RP data only with three joint SP–RP estimation techniques, each assigning a different weight to the influence of SP and RP data in coefficient estimates. Statistically, models allowing more RP influence outperform SP influenced models. However, results suggest that because the RP data in this study is afflicted by multicollinearity, techniques that allow more SP influence in the beta estimates while maintaining RP data for calibrating vehicle class constraints produce more realistic estimates of willingness to pay. Furthermore, SP influenced coefficient estimates also translate to more realistic behavioral parameters for CIMS, allowing more sensitivity to policy simulations. 相似文献