全文获取类型
收费全文 | 774篇 |
免费 | 59篇 |
国内免费 | 3篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 56篇 |
工业经济 | 43篇 |
计划管理 | 135篇 |
经济学 | 276篇 |
综合类 | 52篇 |
运输经济 | 46篇 |
旅游经济 | 34篇 |
贸易经济 | 83篇 |
农业经济 | 17篇 |
经济概况 | 94篇 |
出版年
2024年 | 2篇 |
2023年 | 29篇 |
2022年 | 15篇 |
2021年 | 20篇 |
2020年 | 34篇 |
2019年 | 33篇 |
2018年 | 37篇 |
2017年 | 50篇 |
2016年 | 42篇 |
2015年 | 34篇 |
2014年 | 45篇 |
2013年 | 110篇 |
2012年 | 47篇 |
2011年 | 35篇 |
2010年 | 32篇 |
2009年 | 40篇 |
2008年 | 40篇 |
2007年 | 39篇 |
2006年 | 24篇 |
2005年 | 19篇 |
2004年 | 22篇 |
2003年 | 15篇 |
2002年 | 12篇 |
2001年 | 16篇 |
2000年 | 4篇 |
1999年 | 5篇 |
1998年 | 9篇 |
1997年 | 7篇 |
1996年 | 4篇 |
1995年 | 5篇 |
1994年 | 3篇 |
1993年 | 2篇 |
1992年 | 1篇 |
1991年 | 1篇 |
1990年 | 1篇 |
1984年 | 1篇 |
1982年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有836条查询结果,搜索用时 14 毫秒
81.
基于 2013 年中国家庭收入调查(CHIP)数据,运用条件代际收入弹性法,探讨了不同类型社会资本对农村居民代际收入流动性的影响机制。实证研究结果表明,父代结构性社会资本和认知性社会资本均可以提升农村居民代际收入流动性,子代社会经济地位在父代结构性社会资本和代际收入流动性的关系中起到部分中介作用。进一步的异质性分析结果发现,父代结构性社会资本对不同性别子代和不同年代出生子代的代际收入流动性均有显著的促进作用,而父代认知性社会资本仅能够提升男性子代、以及 70 后和 90 后子代的代际收入流动性。此外,从代际收入流动模式来看,不管子代是从最低收入阶层流向中低收入阶层,还是由最低收入阶层流向中等以上收入阶层,父代结构性社会资本和认知性社会资本均可以提升农村居民代际收入流动性。 相似文献
82.
《The Scandinavian economic history review / [the Scandanavian Society for Economic and Social History and Historical Geography]》2012,60(3):249-250
ABSTRACTEconomic theory predicts that regional wages will converge as transport and communication technologies bring labour markets together. An exploration of this transition from labour market segmentation to unification requires long-term evidence of nominal wages and cost of living by region. This paper presents new evidence of wages for male manufacturing workers and cost-of-living indices across 24 Swedish counties between 1860 and 2009. Our findings indicate that the Swedish regional wage differentials were a great deal larger in the 1860s than in the 2000s. Most of the compression took place between the 1860s and World War I, as well as in the 1930s and during World War II. Differences in expenditures on housing impact on our assessment of convergence in the post-World War II decades: the nominal measure declines, while the real one stays constant. Our concluding discussion engages with the assumption that before World War I, regional wage convergence was associated with labour mobility, spurred by improved communication and transportation technologies as well as by the implementation of modern employment contracts. In the 1930s and 1940s, in contrast, regional wage convergence can be traced to high unionisation and centralised collective bargaining in the labour market, two distinguishing features of the Swedish Model. 相似文献
83.
Julia Maisenbacher 《New Political Economy》2015,20(6):871-893
The research on European Union (EU) external relations and the EU's own official discourse frequently portray the EU as a soft power that provides its neighbourhood with good governance principles. The European Mobility Partnerships (EU MPs) can be considered the most recent manifestation of this rhetoric. Studies on EU MPs reflect a narrow understanding of power. This paper aims to contribute to a more comprehensive understanding of the power dimension inherent in the EU's external relations. It develops a neogramscian theoretical framework to challenge the rhetoric of the EU as a soft power and normative hegemon. Drawing on semi-structured expert interviews and textual analysis of documents, it seeks to reveal whether and in what ways socio-economic power dynamics shape the EU MPs. This article argues that while, at the beginning, the design of the EU MPs as a policy tool has been very much influenced by neoliberal ideas such as the market-oriented liberalisation of mobility and the flexibilisation of labour, implementation is marked by the neo-mercantilist approach of restricting immigration and maximising the efficiency of readmission. Applying a critical political economy concept of power is helpful in understanding how market forces influence EU external migration policy, transcending a narrow understanding of power. 相似文献
84.
In this paper, we show that between 1975 and 2005, Sweden exhibited a pattern of job polarization with expansions of the highest‐ and lowest‐paid jobs compared to middle‐wage jobs. The most popular explanation for such a pattern is the hypothesis of task‐biased technological change, where technological progress reduces the demand for routine middle‐wage jobs but increases the demand for non‐routine jobs located at the tails of the job–wage distribution. However, our estimates do not support this explanation for the 1970s and 1980s. Stronger evidence for task‐biased technological change, albeit not conclusive, is found for the 1990s and 2000s. In particular, there is both a statistically and economically significant growth of non‐routine jobs and a decline of routine jobs. However, results for wages are mixed; while task‐biased technological change cannot explain changes in between‐occupation wage differentials, it does have considerable explanatory power for changes in within‐occupation wage differentials. 相似文献
85.
Dr. Ivan Privalko 《Economics of Transition》2021,29(3):405-429
This article considers age and gender differences in the probability and consequences of job mobility in Russia. Little is known about who is mobile and whether mobility impacts wages once the characteristics of movers are controlled for. Results show a gender difference in the likelihood of exit but not promotion. Results also show that promotions have a positive effect only on the wages of young women, but young men's wages are not affected. Further, young men see a significant decrease in wages following an exit, while young women are not affected by firm exit. The article shows that early mobility is particularly important for women, who earn less overall. Results help to understand processes of inequality in wages and conditions that occur due to sorting, and the importance of promotions as ‘life chances’ which lead to ‘career-track jobs’. Gender differences in securing such life chances may help to understand gaps in earnings, which emerge later. 相似文献
86.
Using data from the European Union Statistics on Income and Living Conditions, this paper investigates wage inequality and wage mobility in Europe. Decomposing inequality into within‐ and between‐group inequality, we analyze to what extent wage inequality and mobility can be explained by observable characteristics. Furthermore, we investigate which individual and household characteristics determine transitions within the wage distribution. We find that overall, mobility reduces wage inequality. While a large part of wage inequality is due to unobservable characteristics, the equalizing effect of mobility mainly occurs within groups. Furthermore, both personal and household characteristics play an important role for wage transitions. Finally, our findings reveal large cross‐country differences across Europe. 相似文献
87.
文章扩展了贸易成本的范围,认为贸易成本不仅包括产品运输成本,而且也包括要素流动成本,并引入前后向产业联系,在此基础上发展了可解的中心一外围模型,并探讨了在各种条件下相应的经济学含义,认为在推动我国区域经济一体化的进程中,对落后地区的技术支持必不可少,并应重视区域问产业发展的互动,否则,我国区域经济一体化进程将难以有效推进。 相似文献
88.
Katharina Jenderny 《Review of Income and Wealth》2016,62(2):245-265
I analyze German top income mobility using micro‐level panel data of personal income tax returns which are highly representative for top income taxpayers for the years 2001–06. Top income mobility is assessed in three dimensions: (i) persistence in top income fractiles and its stability over time, (ii) measures of individual mobility that are not dependent on the fractile size: the degree of mobility between equally sized groups and mobility in ranks, and (iii) mobility's impact on top income shares. Persistence in top income fractiles is comparatively high and fairly stable across the analyzed period. Top income recipients are less prone to downward mobility and see less variation in annual ranks than less rich tax units. Mobility's impact on income concentration is moderate. The top percentile's share is reduced by roughly 5 percent over six years. 相似文献
89.
This study attempts to reassess the evidence on the degree of capital mobility and crowding out by applying a varying coefficients model to data on 19 OECD countries over the 1971–1999 period. Our period-specific results strongly support the crowding-out effect as well as the low capital mobility argument for this group of countries as a whole. However, the strength of the crowding-out effect appears to weaken and the degree of capital mobility to increase in the 1990s as compared to the 1970s and 1980s. We also classify countries into five groups according to the relative size of the government sector. Our group-specific results indicate that the degree of capital mobility is generally lower and the crowding-out effect generally stronger, in country groups with smaller governments. The differences are especially evident when we compare the group with largest government size with all other groups, those differences between the latter being much more modest. However, significant differences in the country-specific results suggest that it is prudent to be cautious when we draw conclusions about crowding-out and capital mobility for specific countries from the period-wise or group-wise results. This is particularly important in drawing policy implications for specific countries. 相似文献
90.
农村经济精英与村域发展 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
随着市场经济的发展,农村经济精英逐渐成为农村众多精英中的主流精英,也成为村域发展的一支新型带动力量。文章运用文献的方法,在综述基础上指出了目前中国农村经济精英的概念、类型、发展现状及在村域发展中的作用,总结提出村域发展不同阶段农村经济精英的不同作用,并在此基础上指出了目前该方面需要加强研究的问题域。 相似文献