全文获取类型
收费全文 | 8301篇 |
免费 | 232篇 |
国内免费 | 4篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 1522篇 |
工业经济 | 555篇 |
计划管理 | 1853篇 |
经济学 | 1398篇 |
综合类 | 132篇 |
运输经济 | 192篇 |
旅游经济 | 136篇 |
贸易经济 | 1442篇 |
农业经济 | 691篇 |
经济概况 | 616篇 |
出版年
2025年 | 3篇 |
2024年 | 6篇 |
2023年 | 34篇 |
2022年 | 36篇 |
2021年 | 270篇 |
2020年 | 388篇 |
2019年 | 780篇 |
2018年 | 526篇 |
2017年 | 560篇 |
2016年 | 520篇 |
2015年 | 513篇 |
2014年 | 552篇 |
2013年 | 775篇 |
2012年 | 625篇 |
2011年 | 539篇 |
2010年 | 363篇 |
2009年 | 349篇 |
2008年 | 383篇 |
2007年 | 305篇 |
2006年 | 260篇 |
2005年 | 199篇 |
2004年 | 148篇 |
2003年 | 108篇 |
2002年 | 83篇 |
2001年 | 54篇 |
2000年 | 61篇 |
1999年 | 36篇 |
1998年 | 9篇 |
1997年 | 7篇 |
1996年 | 8篇 |
1995年 | 5篇 |
1994年 | 4篇 |
1993年 | 6篇 |
1992年 | 4篇 |
1991年 | 5篇 |
1990年 | 2篇 |
1989年 | 3篇 |
1988年 | 1篇 |
1986年 | 1篇 |
1985年 | 2篇 |
1984年 | 2篇 |
1982年 | 2篇 |
排序方式: 共有8537条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
991.
随着现代经济的发展,石油与金融的结合越来越紧,石油金融化趋势日益凸显。因此,为应对国际石油价格的未来走势,保障中国金融体系和中国经济的安全和长期稳定发展,中国迫切需要制定石油金融体系。新形势下中国石油金融体系构建的战略取向为:多层次构建石油交易市场体系;多渠道营造石油银行系统;多途径形成石油基金组合;多方位灵活运用石油外汇等。 相似文献
992.
Maman Setiawan 《International Journal of the Economics of Business》2019,26(2):315-326
AbstractThis research investigates the persistence of price–cost margin (PCM) and technical efficiency (TE) of firms and the relation between these two factors in 44 subsectors of the Indonesian food and beverage industry in the period 1980–2014. Data envelopment analysis with a bootstrapping approach is applied to estimate TE. An autoregressive model, accounting for endogeneity, is applied to estimate the persistence coefficients of PCM and TE. A cross-sectional regression model is also applied to estimate the relation between the persistence of the PCM and the persistence of TE. The results show that for these food and beverage firms, high PCM and low TE persist. Furthermore, the persistence of PCM negatively affects the persistence of TE in the industry. 相似文献
993.
自来水行业是社会公益性的自然垄断行业,其中存在市场失灵。通过模型分析对自来水价格管制前后的各受益主体显示,政府对垄断行业的价格管制是十分必要的。通过合理的价格管制,最终增加社会净福利。最后,提出要重视听证会制度在价格管制中的作用,以及要完善政策制定过程。 相似文献
994.
1978年以来的人民币实际汇率呈现出长期的贬值态势,本文结合中国经济改革的历程深入分析了实际汇率贬值的内在机制,认为市场化进程中的制度变迁和技术进步是其根本原因。而目前经济的内外失衡所引发的实际汇率和名义汇率的升值压力,本质上是深层次市场化改革推进受阻后经济结构扭曲的外在表现。本文认为,以汇率形成机制改革为主要内容的名义的市场化改革只能缓解而无法根除这种压力,推行土地、劳动力和自然资源等要素价格在内的实际的市场改革才是纠正内外失衡,缓解汇率升值压力的治本之道。 相似文献
995.
The result by Morrison (1985) and Morrison and Schwarzt (1994) that there is an one-to-one relationship between the rate of economic capacity utilization and ratio of cost elasticities at the temporary and the full equilibrium has been instrumental in past studies on measuring economic capacity utilization and on adjusting indexes of productivity growth for temporary equilibrium. In this paper, dynamic duality and comparative dynamics are employed to assess the behavior of cost elasticity along an optimal path to the steady state. The analysis suggests that no a priori relationship exists between economic capacity utilization and elasticity of cost. The absence of an a priori relationship between these two economic variables implies that theoretical and empirical results based on past notions about the dynamic behavior of cost elasticity may have to be reconsidered. 相似文献
996.
Marianne Simonsen 《The Scandinavian journal of economics》2010,112(3):570-594
Using local variation between municipalities, I analyze the degree to which the price of high‐quality publicly subsidized childcare affects female employment following maternity leave. Importantly, prices are income dependent and thus likely endogenous, yet by exploiting information on minimum income compensation during non‐employment, I bypass this problem. The results show that the price negatively affects employment. A price increase of €1 per month decreases employment by 0.08%, which corresponds to a price elasticity of −0.17. These effects prevail during the first 12 months after childbirth. I also find that availability of childcare increases employment. 相似文献
997.
998.
999.
Shami Ghosh 《Journal of Agrarian Change》2016,16(2):255-290
Based on a synthesis of the empirical scholarship on England and Germany, this paper demonstrates that in both regions, rural socio‐economic developments from c.1200 to c.1800 are similar: this period witnesses the rise to numerical predominance and growing economic significance of the ‘sub‐peasant classes’, which had a growing impact on the market as a result of their increasing market dependence, and from which – towards the end of the period – a rural proletariat emerged. Against the influential theory of Robert Brenner, it is argued that the period c.1200–c.1400 cannot really be categorized as ‘feudal’ according to Brenner's definition; and ‘agrarian capitalism’ does not adequately describe the socio‐economic system that obtained by the end of the sixteenth century. A genuine transition to capitalism is only evident from after c.1750, and can be found in Germany as well as in England; it is predicated both on ideological shifts and on the evolution of the rural proletariat, which is only found in large numbers by or after c.1800. 相似文献
1000.
We identify farms’ optimal investment path in capital assets and compare it with their actual investment to assess the direction and extent of deviation from the optimal investment. A probit model is further used to investigate the determinants of the probability that a farmer over‐ or under‐invests in capital assets. We use a panel dataset of Dutch dairy farms over the period 2003–2013, and find that most farms under‐invest in capital assets during the study period. Although the number of farms that had over‐invested in capital assets is relatively small, these farms account for the biggest share of total investment in capital assets. The probit results show that liquidity, agricultural support payments, age, land tenure and standard output size are important variables explaining the likelihood of over‐and under‐investment. 相似文献