首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   767篇
  免费   18篇
  国内免费   2篇
财政金融   89篇
工业经济   12篇
计划管理   103篇
经济学   349篇
综合类   41篇
运输经济   5篇
旅游经济   7篇
贸易经济   54篇
农业经济   17篇
经济概况   110篇
  2024年   2篇
  2023年   14篇
  2022年   9篇
  2021年   16篇
  2020年   30篇
  2019年   29篇
  2018年   25篇
  2017年   30篇
  2016年   22篇
  2015年   20篇
  2014年   22篇
  2013年   74篇
  2012年   51篇
  2011年   73篇
  2010年   44篇
  2009年   37篇
  2008年   48篇
  2007年   43篇
  2006年   43篇
  2005年   34篇
  2004年   25篇
  2003年   25篇
  2002年   19篇
  2001年   16篇
  2000年   9篇
  1999年   10篇
  1998年   2篇
  1997年   3篇
  1996年   4篇
  1995年   2篇
  1990年   1篇
  1989年   1篇
  1984年   3篇
  1983年   1篇
排序方式: 共有787条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
781.
We explore the suitability of the minimum wage as a policy instrument for reducing emerging income inequality created by new technologies. For this, we implement a binding minimum wage in a task-based framework, in which tasks are conducted by machines, low-skill, and high-skill workers. In this framework, an increasing minimum wage reduces the inequality between the low-skill wage and the other factor prices, whereas the share of income of low-skill workers in the national income is nonincreasing. Then, we analyze the impact of an automating economy along the extensive and intensive margins. In a setting with a minimum wage, it can be shown that automation at the extensive margin and the creation of new, labor-intensive tasks do not increase the aggregate output in general, as the displacement of low-skill workers counteracts the positive effects of cost-savings. Finally, we highlight a potential trade-off between less inequality of the factor prices and greater inequality of the income distribution when a minimum wage is introduced into an automating economy.  相似文献   
782.
This paper aims to investigate the impact of the Covid-19 pandemic on technological knowledge, wage inequality, and economic growth, by proposing a Direct-Technical-Change model with two economies, an Innovative and other Follower. Six hypotheses are considered: (i) decrease in the unskilled-labor supply, (ii) decrease in the absolute advantage of unskilled labor, (iii) decrease in the intensity of the unskilled sector, (iv) hypothesis (i) combined with a lower decrease in the skilled-labor supply, (v) hypothesis (ii) combined with a lower decrease in the absolute advantage of skilled labor, (vi) all the variations previously considered. By comparing the steady states before and after the shock, we find an increase in the technological-knowledge bias that favors the skill-intensive sector, which positively affects the skill premium. However, in hypotheses (i) and (iv), the decrease in the relative supply of unskilled labor dominates the effect on the skill premium, which thus decreases. The economic growth rate is always penalized except for hypothesis (iii). Hypotheses (ii) and (iv) are undesirable because they increase wage inequality and penalize economic growth. Governments should support innovative activity, the engine of technological-knowledge progress, and thus economic growth, but with caution not to exacerbate the skill premium.  相似文献   
783.
Popular discussion presumes minimum wage increases primarily drive wage gains for minimum wage workers. We investigate this presumption using the Current Population Survey to assess the fraction of minimum wage workers receiving raises after 12 months. This fraction is moderately higher following state minimum wage increases, and positively correlated with several measures of labor market tightness. Finally, wage gains frequently follow industry and/or occupation switches, highlighting the importance of career progression for earnings growth among entry-level workers. Career progression and increases in labor demand rather than minimum wage increases appear to drive most wage gains for minimum wage workers.  相似文献   
784.
Work–family policies are meant to support labor force participants, but they often result in lower rewards for those who use them. Based on the ideal worker norm framework and signalling theory, we hypothesise that parental leave duration will result in lower wage growth, above and beyond that of having children. The 1997 National Longitudinal Survey of Youth data from 2000 to 2015 are used to test the hypotheses with a longitudinal sample (14 waves) of individuals in the United States who worked before and after taking parental leave (n = 6723). Discontinuous growth models are used to predict the penalty for parental leave duration for men and women. We find that both men and women suffer from a lower hourly wage growth for taking longer parental leave and that there are more severe penalties for taking paid parental leave than taking unpaid parental leave. Practitioner notes What is currently known?
  • utilization of parental leave is significantly related to the wellbeing of employees and their families.
  • However, employees are penalized for taking parental leave.
What this study adds?
  • Paid parental leave, which is mostly available to skilled, professional employees carries a noticeable early-career wage penalty, but the use of unpaid leave, does not.
  • Both men and women are penalized for taking parental leave, but the longer parental leaves women take increase the gender pay gap.
Implications for practitioners:
  • HR practitioners should monitor whether employees are penalized for taking parental leave.
  • HR practitioners should try incentivizing male employees to take parental leave that is comparable to the one taken by their female employees.
  相似文献   
785.
To stimulate economic growth, the Chinese government implemented three consecutive policies between 2016 and 2019 to reduce the corporate endowment insurance contribution ratio (CEICR), the highest payment item for Chinese companies. Using China's CEICR reduction policies as a quasi-natural experiment, this paper evaluates the impact of corporate payment burden reduction on employee wages. Generally, reducing CEICR appears to prompt companies to increase employee wages. Corporate cash flow is a possible channel of influence. Moreover, the positive effect is found to be more pronounced in companies that are more labor intensive, performing better in labor payment compliance, and located in regions with higher pressure for elderly care. This paper offers evidence in favor of implementing CEICR reduction policies from the perspective of improving the well-being of employees.  相似文献   
786.
The advantages of multinational enterprises (MNEs) over domestic firms have been widely acknowledged in several streams of literature. However, a more refined analysis on the sources of their advantages is lacking. Exploiting minimum wage hikes in China as an exogenous shock, we theorize that, due to multinational advantages, the employment of multinational subsidiaries may be less affected by minimum wages than that of domestic firms, and that their multinational advantages arise from both operational and financial advantages. Using nation-wide longitudinal firm data from 1998 to 2007 and border discontinuity design (BDD) to estimate the causal effects, we find supportive evidence for our hypotheses. We contribute to the literature on multinational advantages and minimum wages.  相似文献   
787.
以2011—2019年我国A股上市公司为研究对象,通过手动收集企业董事高管责任保险及绿色专利数据,实证考察董事高管责任保险对绿色创新的影响,结果发现:①董事高管责任保险能够显著促进企业绿色创新,即董事高管责任保险是企业绿色创新的激励工具,而非管理层阻碍绿色创新的自利手段;②通过Heckman两阶段模型、倾向得分匹配缓解可能存在的内生性问题,并经过一系列其它稳健性检验后,基本结论仍保持不变;③董事高管责任保险对绿色创新的促进作用在不同规模、不同股权集中度的企业间存在差异,主要表现为对中小型企业的影响大于大型企业,对股权较为集中企业的影响大于股权分散企业。从董事高管责任保险这一全新视角对企业绿色创新进行解读,可为加速我国上市企业董事高管责任保险知识普及,驱动企业绿色创新跨越式发展提供理论支撑。  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号