全文获取类型
收费全文 | 169篇 |
免费 | 0篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 6篇 |
工业经济 | 3篇 |
计划管理 | 24篇 |
经济学 | 60篇 |
综合类 | 21篇 |
运输经济 | 2篇 |
旅游经济 | 10篇 |
贸易经济 | 17篇 |
农业经济 | 6篇 |
经济概况 | 20篇 |
出版年
2024年 | 1篇 |
2023年 | 6篇 |
2021年 | 3篇 |
2020年 | 8篇 |
2019年 | 13篇 |
2018年 | 6篇 |
2017年 | 10篇 |
2016年 | 7篇 |
2015年 | 7篇 |
2014年 | 7篇 |
2013年 | 22篇 |
2012年 | 5篇 |
2011年 | 8篇 |
2010年 | 2篇 |
2009年 | 5篇 |
2008年 | 10篇 |
2007年 | 16篇 |
2006年 | 6篇 |
2005年 | 4篇 |
2004年 | 7篇 |
2003年 | 5篇 |
2002年 | 4篇 |
2001年 | 4篇 |
1999年 | 1篇 |
1988年 | 1篇 |
1986年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有169条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
11.
This paper develops and estimates models of family and sex-specific emigration, as well as the sex composition of this emigration, from 12 European source countries to the U.S. for the period 1870–1910. The models are based on the distinction between economic migrants (males, single females, and some married females) and tied or trailing migrants (females) and are estimated with panel data, including data that relate to the occupational/industrial structure of male and female economic activity in source countries. Hausman-Taylor instrumental variable estimates suggest that although both males and females responded to labor-market signals, males were more responsive than females to per capita GDP differences. Moreover, compared to the rest of Europe, Ireland, and Scandinavia were the sources of many young, single male, and female migrants, who responded strongly to gaps in economic opportunities. In fact, much of the European response to such gaps appears to be due to migrants from Ireland and Scandinavia. Females tended to originate in English-speaking countries and countries that were agriculturally oriented. Service and manufacturing jobs in source countries discouraged the migration of females relative to males. Males tended to follow recent migrants more than females, but females responded more to long-term influences as measured by stocks of migrants from their source countries who had previously settled in the U.S. Countries with high birth rates had relatively fewer female emigrants, whereas those with high rates of natural increase 20 years earlier experienced relatively more male emigration. Intact families, other family members (including family-strategy male migrants and trailing female migrants), and single males and females responded strongly to economic incentives, but the singles were most responsive followed by family-strategy males. 相似文献
12.
Jonathan Wadsworth 《Fiscal Studies》2013,34(1):55-82
A rise in population caused by increased immigration is sometimes accompanied by concerns that the increase in population puts additional or differential pressure on welfare services, which might affect the net fiscal contribution of immigrants. The UK and Germany have experienced significant increases in immigration in recent years and this study uses longitudinal data from both countries to examine whether immigrants differ in their use of health services from native-born individuals on arrival and over time. While immigrants to Germany, but not the UK, are more likely to self-report poor health than the native-born population, the samples of immigrants use hospital and GP services at broadly the same rate as the native-born populations in both countries. Controls for observed and unobserved differences between immigrants and native-born sample populations make little difference to these broad findings. 相似文献
13.
全球化语境下的欧洲化移民治理困境 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
全球化造就了大批国际移民并加剧了移民问题。欧洲一体化过程作为经济全球化的微缩样本,展示了移民问题在超国家治理方面的经验和智慧,进一步显示了非政府组织和公民社会参与的必要性。欧盟移民问题已经成为涉及政治、经济、文化、民族、宗教和社会的复杂问题。由移民所引发的混乱正在打破民族地域界限向全球扩散,形成了非传统安全对传统主权的拆解,需要一种崭新的跨国主义治理模式以强化其有效性。 相似文献
14.
15.
Rich countries often face sizeable illegal migration. This paper suggests that these countries would use the financial aid which they give to the source countries as an instrument to prevent illegal immigration. The core of this policy is to allow the source countries to compete for the pre-determined aid, which would be distributed according to the cross-proportion of the apprehended illegal aliens. Moreover, we show that it may be beneficial for the rich country to split the source countries into competing pairs rather than allowing all of them to compete jointly. The rich country has basically two policy means: funds allocated to strengthening its border control; and the foreign aid given to the source countries. The multi-country general equilibrium model presented shows how the rich country, by choosing an appropriate mix of these two policy means, can minimize the number of illegal immigrants subject to its budget constrain.Received: 15 August 2002, Accepted: 21 January 2004, JEL Classification:
F22Nava Kahana, Tikva Lecker: The authors are grateful to two anonymous referees for their valuable comments. 相似文献
16.
经过多年的建设发展,C区已经成为首都城市发展新区,但在快速发展过程中,出现了外来人口快速增长的现象,加重了社会治理负担,也使C区成为了B市唯一的“人口倒挂区”。因此,外来人口的服务与管理亟须创新思路,重新定位。通过对C区外来人口现状特征进行分析,找出当前外来人口服务与管理中存在问题,并对C区的发展提出对策建议。 相似文献
17.
This paper gives a brief overview of China's family planning policy which, although recently relaxed, still controls a large swath of the population. Unofficially known as the ‘one‐child policy’, it resulted from the social strife of the 1970s coupled with a Malthusian pessimism concerning the capability of the still largely closed and isolated Chinese economy to care for itself. We discuss the motivations for the policy, the unfortunate demographic future that it will create, and some policy reforms that can be undertaken today. 相似文献
18.
基于乡村产业振兴视角构建理论模型,探究了农业人口转移引发要素投入变化影响乡村产业结构的机制,并采用2001—2013年中国216个地级城市的分行业数据进行实证检验。研究发现:(1)农业人口转移在短期对乡村产业升级具有明显的抑制作用,但长期的投入要素替代效应有利于提升农业专业化服务水平,优化乡村产业结构;(2)农业人口转移显著提高了农业部门的资本劳动比,促进了乡村产业结构转型升级和专业服务水平的提升,但人力资本趋于恶化,具有较大的负面影响;(3)农业人口转移导致的相对劳动成本变化对东部地区影响更大,而中西部地区乡村产业结构受人力资本的制约更为明显。加快农业转移人口市民化的同时注重人力资本回流和科技投入,促进乡村产业转型升级,对乡村振兴战略具有重要的政策涵义。 相似文献
19.
While imperfect substitutability between native and immigrant workers is an important mechanism in estimating the wage effects of immigration, its empirical literature is concentrated on the context of only a few countries. Using occupation task-intensity data from a unique Korean data set, we demonstrate that relatively skilled native Korean workers respond to increased low-skilled immigration by pursuing jobs more intensive in communication and cognitive tasks. This native response is mainly pronounced in knowledge-intensive service sectors and leads to an improvement in average wages in these sectors. Our results support the general assumption that the labor market impact of immigration critically depends on whether native and immigrant workers are substitutes or complements in production. 相似文献
20.
We construct a disaggregated rural economywide model with a focus on gender and immigration as well as on the allocation of time to wage work, household production activities, and housework (reproduction). We use this model to simulate the impacts of the Dominican Republic-Central American Free Trade Agreement (DR-CAFTA) on rural incomes and welfare in the Dominican Republic. We find that elimination of agricultural import tariffs hurts both agricultural and non-agricultural households, via adverse factor-market effects, but impacts vary substantially by workers’ gender and country of origin. Females and Haitian immigrants tend to fare better than Dominican males, and there are ramifications for both market and non-market activities. 相似文献