全文获取类型
收费全文 | 1359篇 |
免费 | 28篇 |
国内免费 | 3篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 204篇 |
工业经济 | 119篇 |
计划管理 | 155篇 |
经济学 | 302篇 |
综合类 | 107篇 |
运输经济 | 26篇 |
旅游经济 | 13篇 |
贸易经济 | 248篇 |
农业经济 | 16篇 |
经济概况 | 200篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 16篇 |
2022年 | 42篇 |
2021年 | 45篇 |
2020年 | 47篇 |
2019年 | 53篇 |
2018年 | 33篇 |
2017年 | 42篇 |
2016年 | 50篇 |
2015年 | 37篇 |
2014年 | 81篇 |
2013年 | 72篇 |
2012年 | 57篇 |
2011年 | 110篇 |
2010年 | 56篇 |
2009年 | 78篇 |
2008年 | 102篇 |
2007年 | 100篇 |
2006年 | 99篇 |
2005年 | 83篇 |
2004年 | 49篇 |
2003年 | 40篇 |
2002年 | 23篇 |
2001年 | 15篇 |
2000年 | 12篇 |
1999年 | 11篇 |
1998年 | 10篇 |
1997年 | 8篇 |
1996年 | 3篇 |
1995年 | 1篇 |
1994年 | 3篇 |
1993年 | 3篇 |
1992年 | 1篇 |
1991年 | 1篇 |
1985年 | 4篇 |
1983年 | 2篇 |
1982年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有1390条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
101.
This paper estimates a frequency equation to explain the determinants of network airline service levels at their hub airports. Drawing on European data for 2002–2013, we find that network airlines reduce frequencies when the share of low-cost airlines increases both on the route and at the hub airport. On the contrary, frequency choices of network airlines are not affected by competition from low-cost airlines operating in nearby secondary airports. We also find some evidence that mergers in Europe may result in a re-organization of the route structure in favor of the hubs of the larger airline. 相似文献
102.
We develop a Generalized Nash Equilibrium network model for post-disaster humanitarian relief by nongovernmental organizations (NGOs). NGOs derive utility from providing relief supplies to victims of the disaster at demand points in a supply chain context while competing with each other for financial funds provided by donations. The shared constraints consist of lower and upper bounds for demand for relief items at the demand points to reduce materiel convergence or congestion. This game theory problem is reformulated as an optimization problem and numerical examples and a theoretical case study on Hurricane Katrina given. 相似文献
103.
China launched the Shanghai Free Trade Zone (FTZ) Program on September 29, 2013 in a bid to reduce administrative interventions, ease restrictions on investments, further open up its financial system, and internationalize its currency to booster shipping, logistics, and commerce. This article aims to present a background of the Shanghai FTZ and some reflections on it. China’s economic reconstruction has made a major impact on its port cities. Competitions between ports are gradually evolving into competitions between supply chains, with ports no longer considered as isolated links in the transport chain but rather as integral links in the supply chain. Ports are transitioning into fourth-generation ports with the establishment of logistics and value-added activities, which are developed in conjunction with local industrial and service businesses. In this trend, China’s port cities can provide a wide range of value-added services and become centers of commodity flow, capital flow, and information flow. Specifically, the combined effects of driving the development of peripheral industries and actively coordinating the activities of relevant parties help regulate the operations of the entire supply chain to obtain potential value-added benefits. The implementation of the Shanghai FTZ will not only stimulate trade but will also bring increased shipping and finance opportunities to the city. With free trade as the new direction and focus of the country’s economic initiatives, the Shanghai FTZ will hopefully lay the groundwork for a new round of reforms and restructuring of the Chinese economy. 相似文献
104.
T.N. Srinivasan 《Japan and the World Economy》1997,9(4):447-465
The most prominent exception to the cardinal ‘most favoured nation’ principle of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) of 1947 is in its Article XXIV relating to Customs Unions (CUs) and Free Trade Areas (FTAs). This article required, first, the general incidence of the duties and regulations of commerce imposed by members of the CU with respect to trade with non-members shall not on the whole be higher or more restrictive than those that were applicable prior to the formation of CU or FTA, and, second, that substantially all the trade among members be free. Neither requirement was very operational, because the phrases ‘general incidence’ and ‘substantially all’ being difficult legal concepts to apply. The agreement of 1994 establishing the World Trade Organization (WTO) has made ‘general incidence’ precise by defining it import-weighted average of height of barriers but without offering any rationale for the definition. Now that preferential trading arrangements such as FTAs are proliferating, reform of Article XXIV is of importance. This paper describes alternative approaches to the central question of common external tariffs of a CU. Taking off from the work of Kemp and Wan who showed the existence of a common external tariff of CU that keeps the welfare of non-members unchanged while revising that of the CU as compared to the situation prior to the formation of CU, it characterizes such a tariff structure for two leading benchmark examples as consumption-weighted average of pre-union tariffs and subsidies in the member countries. 相似文献
105.
缑杰 《湖北财经高等专科学校学报》2011,(3):58-61
鄂商文化源远流长,博大精深,鄂商文化是湖北商人、湖北企业的一笔巨大财富。继承与弘扬鄂商文化具有重大的历史与现实意义。当代的湖北商人要在反省中打造崭新的鄂商文化,加强企业文化的建设,重新塑造自己,重新构建优秀的企业文化,不断增强企业竞争力,助推中部崛起。 相似文献
106.
中外银行中间业务发展的比较研究 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
中间业务是现代商业银行发展最快、种类最多、潜力最大的业务领域。文章全面分析了中外银行中间业务各自发展的竞争优势与劣势,提出了我国商业银行中间业务发展的对策与建议。 相似文献
107.
Using a comparative-static general equilibrium model in the context of the Western Hemisphere, this paper compares the economic
effects of a “hub-and-spokes” type of bilateral trade configuration (with Chile being the hub) with those of a more comprehensive
regional FTA (namely, the FTAA). The model is augmented to account for the possibility of technology spillovers and its effective
assimilation among participating economies. In particular, absorptive capacity, governance factor, proximity and socio-institutional
congruence conjointly determine an economy’s capacity to capture the technology that is transmitted from the developed spoke
United States to other regions.
JEL no. D58, F13, O33 相似文献
108.
转轨经济的演进基本分为激进和渐进两种路径,波兰和俄罗斯采取的是“大爆炸”式的激进改革路径,而中国采取的是后者。波兰和中国经过改革后快速发展,而俄罗斯的休克疗法却让经济停滞,为什么波兰和中国采取了不同的转轨路径却都获得了成功,而俄罗斯却没有取得预期的效果?本文分析演进路径下的内在原因得出结论,培育竞争与产权改革的先后顺序决定了经济改革的关键。 相似文献
109.
Free sampling and price discounts are important, popular promotional tools used to attract new customers by reducing their risk of trial. The authors investigate pay-what-you-want (PWYW) as an alternative promotional tool to free sampling and price discounts in two field experiments. The authors find significant differences in perceived promotional characteristics and relevant performance measures, such as trial and repeat purchases by new customers. The entertaining and innovative character of PWYW induces many people to try it. PWYW may yield a higher repeat purchase rate of new customers, and sellers using PWYW benefit from higher word-of-mouth behavior. Finally, PWYW yields the highest promotional revenues. 相似文献
110.
Bijoy Rakshit 《International Journal of the Economics of Business》2019,26(2):283-313
AbstractThis paper measures the degree of bank competition in India using a sample of 70 commercial banks over the period 1996–2016. To assess the degree of competition, we estimate the market power of each bank in our sample employing three nonstructural measures: the Lerner index, the adjusted Lerner index, and the Boone indicator. Bank-wise and year-wise estimates of the marginal cost required in all these measures are obtained using the semi-parametric method. The paper further attempts to undertake a comprehensive assessment of competition in Indian banking and identifies various bank-specific, macroeconomic, structural, and contestability indicators, which are supposed to explain level and variation of the degree of competition over time. Empirical findings reveal that public-sector banks in India exercise a relatively higher degree of bank competition compared to private and foreign-sector banks. However, aggregate results support that the Indian banking system is competitive in general. Unlike the structure-conduct-performance paradigm, which advocates that a concentrated banking system impairs competitiveness, our findings reveal that concentration measures hardly exert any effect on bank competition. Rather, contestability measures play a significant role in the determination of bank competition. 相似文献