全文获取类型
收费全文 | 1115篇 |
免费 | 50篇 |
国内免费 | 1篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 26篇 |
工业经济 | 37篇 |
计划管理 | 260篇 |
经济学 | 189篇 |
综合类 | 71篇 |
运输经济 | 10篇 |
旅游经济 | 71篇 |
贸易经济 | 49篇 |
农业经济 | 341篇 |
经济概况 | 112篇 |
出版年
2025年 | 2篇 |
2024年 | 12篇 |
2023年 | 13篇 |
2022年 | 17篇 |
2021年 | 21篇 |
2020年 | 50篇 |
2019年 | 32篇 |
2018年 | 21篇 |
2017年 | 53篇 |
2016年 | 46篇 |
2015年 | 37篇 |
2014年 | 58篇 |
2013年 | 92篇 |
2012年 | 83篇 |
2011年 | 101篇 |
2010年 | 106篇 |
2009年 | 94篇 |
2008年 | 64篇 |
2007年 | 65篇 |
2006年 | 51篇 |
2005年 | 34篇 |
2004年 | 21篇 |
2003年 | 14篇 |
2002年 | 12篇 |
2001年 | 10篇 |
2000年 | 11篇 |
1999年 | 14篇 |
1998年 | 5篇 |
1997年 | 3篇 |
1996年 | 7篇 |
1995年 | 3篇 |
1994年 | 2篇 |
1993年 | 3篇 |
1992年 | 2篇 |
1991年 | 1篇 |
1985年 | 3篇 |
1984年 | 1篇 |
1982年 | 1篇 |
1980年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有1166条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
1.
2.
Majority of the increase in global energy consumption is from China; hence, studying energy issues, especially in China’s manufacturing industry (CMI), is worthwhile and of much interest in the academic field. Based on the translog cost function, we develop a research framework to study the rebound effect of CMI. Considering the effect of asymmetric energy price, we augment the energy-cost function with asymmetric influence constraint of energy price. Again, we add time series data of CMI’s capital, labor, energy, and mid-input to the model to calculate the direct rebound effect of CMI. We find that the rebound effect of CMI is 44.2%, and CMI still has large energy-conservation potentials. Based on the results of this study, some policy recommendations are provided. 相似文献
3.
浅析太阳能在建筑节能领域中的应用 总被引:2,自引:0,他引:2
本文结合目前建筑设计的节能要求,对目前太阳能在建筑节能领域中的应用及发展前景作了比较与分析,谨供大家作参考之用。 相似文献
4.
Benis Egoh Mathieu Rouget Andrew T. Knight Albert S. van Jaarsveld 《Ecological Economics》2007,63(4):714-721
A call has been made for conservation planners to include ecosystem services into their assessments of conservation priority areas. The need to develop an integrated approach to meeting different conservation objectives and a shift in focus towards human wellbeing are some of the motivations behind this call. There is currently no widely accepted approach to planning for ecosystem services. This study contributes towards the development of this approach through a review of conservation assessments and the extent to which they include ecosystem services. Of the 476 conservation assessments identified by a set of search terms on the Web of Science, 100 were randomly selected for this review. Of these only seven had included ecosystem services, while another 13 had referred to ecosystem services as a rationale for conservation without including them in the assessment. The majority of assessments were based on biodiversity pattern data while 19 used data on ecological processes. A total of 11 of these 19 assessments used processes, which could be linked to services. Ecosystem services have witnessed an increase in attention received in conservation assessments since the year 2000, however trends were not apparent beyond this date. In order to assess which types of ecosystem services and how they have been accounted for in conservation assessments, we extended our review to include an additional nine conservation assessments which included ecosystem services. The majority included cultural ecosystem services, followed by regulatory, provisioning and supporting services respectively. We conclude with an analysis of the constraints and opportunities for the integration of ecosystem services into conservation assessments and highlight the urgent need for an appropriate framework for planning for ecosystem services. 相似文献
5.
NGO作为与市场和政府并列的第三支力量在环境保护领域发挥着重要的作用。从NGO在环境领域发挥作用的理论根源入手,分析了NGO在主要发达国家和我国环境保护中的作用,并预测了我国环境领域NGO发展的趋势。 相似文献
6.
A. Lans Bovenberg 《Environmental and Resource Economics》1993,3(3):233-244
Taxes may seem to be the most attractive instrument for curbing the emissions of carbon dioxide. This paper, however, argues that environmental taxes involve a number of serious complications — especially in an open economy riddled with market imperfections like the Netherlands. Therefore, a wide-ranging policy mix is called for. As far as households and sheltered sectors are concerned, regulation can continue to play a major role. Within the context of unilateral policies aimed at exposed sectors, the combination of subsidies and voluntary agreements may be more cost effective than the tax instrument.This paper was prepared for a conference on Energy Taxation in Europe organized by the Stichting voor Economisch Onderzoek (SEO) and held on December 13, 1991 in Amsterdam, the Netherlands. The author would like to thank Sijbren Cnossen, Jarig van Sinderen and one anonymous referee for helpful comments on an earlier draft. 相似文献
7.
Nick Johnstone 《Environmental and Resource Economics》1996,8(3):367-374
In this paper an analysis of the U.K. government's air pollution emissions policy for the residential sector is undertaken. The analysis covers emissions arising from water and space heating, electric appliances and cooking appliances. Using an integrated economic-engineering model, the effects of the Energy Savings Trust and the imposition of Value Added Tax on residential fuel will be evaluated in terms of energy consumption and pollution emissions. It is found that the initial proposed policy was not sufficiently stringent to meet the government's environmental objectives, and that subsequent events have undermined the government's programme even further. Unless alternative policies are introduced, emissions from the residential sector will play an important role in jeopardizing the ability of the U.K. government to meet its international obligations. 相似文献
8.
Jonah Busch 《Ecological Economics》2008,67(3):394-404
Nearly two hundred transboundary protected areas comprise a portion of the global conservation landscape the size of India, with further expansion anticipated. Proponents claim that transboundary protected areas outperform isolated protected areas in achieving conservation objectives, while regional case studies have led critics to challenge this claim. Empirical investigation into the relative performance of transboundary protected areas is fundamentally limited since these areas cannot be directly compared to the isolated protected areas that might otherwise have emerged in the same location. This paper develops a game theory model of park formation to compare counterfactual transboundary and isolated protected areas. The model suggests that under certain conditions, transboundary protected areas can achieve greater conservation and production objectives, even in the absence of international cooperative park management. The paper establishes five sufficient conditions for transboundary protected areas to provide greater national welfare, domestic conservation value, or global conservation value than counterfactual isolated protected areas. These conditions are tested for three common conservation objectives. The results suggest that when the objective of conservation is species persistence or interior habitat, conservation groups should encourage transboundary protected areas. However, when the objective of conservation is to extend reserve coverage to the maximum number of species, conservation groups should encourage protected areas where species richness is greatest, whether or not these areas span international borders. 相似文献
9.
赵中伟 《南京财经大学学报》2008,(1)
在不同的国家中,对投资者保护的法律制度、法律执行质量和会计标准存在很大的差异。在一定程度上,股权集中是对投资者法律保护的替代。对投资者的法律保护与公司价值间存在正相关关系;集中的所有权有助于改善公司价值。为了保护投资者的利益,我国应该完善对投资者的法律保护,提高执法质量和会计质量,促进股权的适度集中。 相似文献
10.
Ryan M. Roberts Kelly W. Jones Andrew Seidl Audrey Ek Hannah Smith 《Journal of Sustainable Tourism》2017,25(10):1353-1366
Protected areas are key to the conservation of global biodiversity and ecosystem services; however, their success is contingent upon adequate funding. One possibility to increase funding for park management is to “sell” a wider suite of ecosystem services “produced” by protected areas, such as carbon sequestration. We conducted 420 tourist surveys to analyze willingness to pay (WTP) for ecosystem service benefits via a conservation fee in the Tambopata National Reserve in Peru. We also interviewed eight tour operators about their perceptions of the proposed fee. The average stated WTP was 15 USD. Sixty-six percent of tourists stated they would pay 10 USD or more, which, if actually paid, would have resulted in 318,000 USD for park management in 2015. Most respondents stated they would pay an additional fee if it supported biodiversity conservation or local ecosystem services, such as water, but less than 10% of tourists were motivated by carbon sequestration as a reason to pay the fee. Most tour operators supported the additional fee. Our findings suggest that tourists are willing to pay higher fees to support conservation but that interest in paying for additional ecosystem services from parks may not extend to global and intangible benefits such as carbon sequestration. 相似文献