全文获取类型
收费全文 | 6093篇 |
免费 | 274篇 |
国内免费 | 20篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 884篇 |
工业经济 | 326篇 |
计划管理 | 939篇 |
经济学 | 1285篇 |
综合类 | 672篇 |
运输经济 | 35篇 |
旅游经济 | 57篇 |
贸易经济 | 863篇 |
农业经济 | 707篇 |
经济概况 | 619篇 |
出版年
2025年 | 19篇 |
2024年 | 78篇 |
2023年 | 115篇 |
2022年 | 94篇 |
2021年 | 166篇 |
2020年 | 274篇 |
2019年 | 210篇 |
2018年 | 177篇 |
2017年 | 199篇 |
2016年 | 210篇 |
2015年 | 207篇 |
2014年 | 326篇 |
2013年 | 506篇 |
2012年 | 447篇 |
2011年 | 499篇 |
2010年 | 342篇 |
2009年 | 336篇 |
2008年 | 397篇 |
2007年 | 341篇 |
2006年 | 376篇 |
2005年 | 263篇 |
2004年 | 168篇 |
2003年 | 148篇 |
2002年 | 102篇 |
2001年 | 85篇 |
2000年 | 73篇 |
1999年 | 43篇 |
1998年 | 41篇 |
1997年 | 36篇 |
1996年 | 20篇 |
1995年 | 19篇 |
1994年 | 21篇 |
1993年 | 19篇 |
1992年 | 9篇 |
1991年 | 9篇 |
1989年 | 1篇 |
1988年 | 1篇 |
1987年 | 3篇 |
1986年 | 1篇 |
1985年 | 2篇 |
1984年 | 2篇 |
1982年 | 1篇 |
1981年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有6387条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
171.
Erik Theissen 《European Finance Review》2003,7(1):1-26
Using data from the Frankfurt Stock Exchange we analyze price formationand liquidity in a non-anonymous environment with similarities to thefloor of the NYSE. Our main hypothesis is that the non-anonymity allows the specialist to assess the probability that atrader trades on the basis of private information. He uses this knowledgeto price discriminate. This can be achieved by quoting a large spread and granting price improvement to traders deemed uninformed.Consistent with our hypothesis we find that price improvement reflects loweradverse selection costs but does not lead to a reduction in the specialist's profit. Further, the quote adjustmentfollowing transactions at the quoted bid or ask price is more pronounced than the quote adjustment aftertransactions at prices inside the spread. Our results indicate that anonymity comes at the cost ofhigher adverse selection risk. 相似文献
172.
杨华 《中央财经大学学报》2007,(4):21-25
城市公用事业改革是当前我国经济体制改革的重点和难点。其改革不仅涉及到经营及运作模式的转变,也涉及到管理体制的转型。就各国公用事业管理的方法及经验来看,价格监管是其最重要的监管方式和手段之一。本文主要从公共管理的视角出发,借鉴和运用绩效管理的理论和方法,以公共定价为切入点,分析了我国城市公用事业的特征及现行定价机制中存在的问题,就如何完善我国城市公用事业公共定价机制提出了几点政策建议。 相似文献
173.
Dean Hanlon;Mehdi Khedmati;Edwin KiaYang Lim;Cameron Truong; 《Journal of Business Finance & Accounting》2024,51(5-6):1337-1377
We empirically capture boardroom backscratching, or cronyism, as when a firm's Chief Executive Officer (CEO) and directors concurrently receive excessive remuneration. We argue that boardroom backscratching can inhibit a board's constructive criticism and monitoring, resulting in a greater likelihood of bad news hoarding. Using 14,104 US firm-year observations spanning 1999–2020, we document a significant positive relationship between boardroom backscratching and stock price crash risk. In additional analyses, we show that boardroom backscratching firms produce less readable annual reports and engage in greater upward real earnings management as channels for concealing bad news. We also find that external monitoring mechanisms weaken the positive association between boardroom backscratching and stock price crash risk. Our main findings withstand several endogeneity tests including propensity score matching, entropy balancing, difference-in-differences analysis using firms’ commencement of boardroom backscratching and CEO turnover event analysis. Our study offers insights to securities regulators and policymakers to revisit the notion of board independence, develop relevant market oversight and revise director and executive remuneration disclosure requirements so as to mitigate adverse stock market performance associated with boardroom backscratching. 相似文献
174.
This paper explores the effect of time‐varying velocity on output responses to policies for reducing/stopping inflation. We study a dynamic general equilibrium model with sticky prices in which we introduce time‐varying velocity. Specifically, we endogenize time‐varying velocity into the model developed by Ireland (1997) for analyzing optimal disinflation. The nonlinear solution method reveals that, depending on velocity, the “disinflationary boom” found by Ball (1994) may disappear even under perfect credibility and that early output losses may be much larger than previously thought. Indeed, we find that a gradual disinflation from a low inflation may even be undesirable. 相似文献
175.
EDWARD NELSON 《Journal of Money, Credit and Banking》2020,52(1):145-164
This paper analyzes Milton Friedman's (1968a) article “The Role of Monetary Policy,” via a discussion of seven fallacies concerning the article. These fallacies are as follows: (i) “The Role of Monetary Policy” was Friedman's first public statement of the natural rate hypothesis. (ii) The Friedman–Phelps Phillips curve was already present in Samuelson and Solow's (1960) analysis. (iii) Friedman's specification of the Phillips curve was based on perfect competition and no nominal rigidities. (iv) Friedman's (1968a) account of monetary policy in the Great Depression contradicted the Monetary History’s version. (v) Friedman (1968a) stated that a monetary expansion will keep the unemployment rate and the real interest rate below their natural rates for two decades. (vi) The zero lower bound on nominal interest rates invalidates the natural rate hypothesis. (vii) Friedman's (1968a) treatment of an interest-rate peg was refuted by the rational expectations revolution. The discussion lays out the reasons why each of these seven items is a fallacy and infers key aspects of the framework underlying Friedman's (1968a) analysis. 相似文献
176.
Antonio Figueiredo 《European Journal of Finance》2018,24(3):183-207
We contribute to the literature by identifying and accurately measuring the drivers of American depositary receipt (ADR) returns contemporaneously across various global time zones. We consider ADRs as two inherently distinct asset classes – stocks and currencies – bundled into one. Throughout, we use a relatively refined, focused, and synchronized minute-by-minute data set on ADRs and all other variables. ADRs from all countries with regular trading hours that overlap with those of the US are considered individually and in clusters. We analyze the interplay of several factors that influence ADRs pricing patterns. Further, we investigate whether such patterns vary by currency, ADR, industry, and emerging/developed market classifications. Our findings indicate that synchronized returns on underlying shares comprise 68.5–74% of the explained returns in ADRs. The remaining 31.5–26% of returns are generated by movements in currency rates. These results are robust across the several models and estimation methods employed. Our findings also show persistent small price discrepancies between ADRs and dollar-adjusted underlying shares on a minute-by-minute basis, implying possible arbitrage opportunities. However, we conclude that trading and ADR conversion costs render such opportunities unattractive. 相似文献
177.
Hoesli Martin Giaccotto Carmelo Favarger Philippe 《The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics》1997,15(1):93-109
This paper develops constant-quality price indices for three categories of real estate-apartment buildings, vacant land, and condominiums—for the city of Geneva, Switzerland. We use both the hedonic and repeat sales models to estimate the price level and, in turn, the rate of price change. The general pattern of each series suggests that real estate prices in Geneva were fairly stable throughout the 1970s, increased sharply during the 1980s, but gave back some of these gains in the early 1990s. Interestingly, the sharp rise in prices in the second half of the 1980s is very similar to that found in some regions of the United States. We also consider the problem, implicit in the repeat sales method, of revisions in previously estimated price indices as additional data become available in later years. 相似文献
178.
Adam J. Ostaszewski Miles B. Gietzmann 《Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting》2008,31(1):1-27
Dye [J Account Res 23 (1985) 123] showed that the optimal disclosure policy, when a manager is randomly endowed with perfect private information,
is upper tailed, i.e., the manager only discloses firm value above an appropriate cutoff level. We interpret this strategically
as an optimal exercise by management of the embedded formal option to report value. Given any disclosure cutoff level, we value the corresponding option using contingent claims analysis. It
is shown that the Dye disclosure cutoff value maximizes the formal option value. We find it to be the minimum possible conditional valuation (conditioned by non-disclosure) which is thus consistent with the intuition that investors should value
conservatively. We show how the Dye cutoff can be interpreted as a strike price in a ‘protective put’ which offers a shield
against risk of disclosure of low value. The strategic analysis is further extended by allowing the probability level that
the manager is informed to be a choice variable. We show that the manager will never choose to be perfectly endowed with information,
and is likely to be more endowed than unendowed. We also present a simple worked example which shows how the total value of
the firm changes once the Dye option is formally incorporated.
相似文献
Miles B. GietzmannEmail: |
179.
本文应用中国股市2007年至2011年的数据,研究了上证50ETF市场价格和基金净值的相关关系,以及折溢价水平及其影响因素。基于ETF的申购赎回和交易机制,在成分股涨跌停板和停牌期间,由于ETF二级市场价格具有价格发现功能,ETF市场价格可能较大偏离(形式上的)ETF净值,造成ETF的异常折溢价,而此类异常折溢价并不是真正的套利机会。另外,上证50ETF的市场价格与基金净值存在显著同步变动的关系;在涨跌停板和停牌期间之外,上证50ETF的折溢价水平低于套利所需的交易成本。本文研究表明,上证50ETF具有较高的定价效率。 相似文献
180.
YONGSEUNG JUNG 《Journal of Money, Credit and Banking》2015,47(4):517-549
This paper shows that the divine‐coincidence does not hold in a sticky price model with external habit if a time‐varying tax rate on labor income is not implemented to fully eliminate the time‐varying distortions associated with external habit and monopoly power in goods market. The required labor income tax rate is inversely related to the risk‐free real interest rate and the markup in the goods market, but it is proportional to the degree of external habit. Under this circumstance, the optimal monetary policy commands a countercyclical interest rate, having a perfect negative correlation with tax rate in the sticky price model with external habit. If a time‐invariant tax is the only fiscal instrument, then the degree of external habit entails a gap between the private marginal rate of substitution between consumption and labor and the social marginal rate of substitution, generating an endogenous trade‐off between the stabilization of welfare‐relevant output gap and inflation. Under this circumstance, price stability is not the optimal policy. The monetary policy authority should optimally try to undo the time‐varying distortions associated with external habit and monopoly power in goods market by deviating from price stability. 相似文献