全文获取类型
收费全文 | 1583篇 |
免费 | 54篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 186篇 |
工业经济 | 59篇 |
计划管理 | 221篇 |
经济学 | 593篇 |
综合类 | 64篇 |
运输经济 | 7篇 |
旅游经济 | 13篇 |
贸易经济 | 144篇 |
农业经济 | 117篇 |
经济概况 | 233篇 |
出版年
2025年 | 1篇 |
2024年 | 8篇 |
2023年 | 17篇 |
2022年 | 10篇 |
2021年 | 26篇 |
2020年 | 59篇 |
2019年 | 65篇 |
2018年 | 34篇 |
2017年 | 47篇 |
2016年 | 49篇 |
2015年 | 59篇 |
2014年 | 117篇 |
2013年 | 141篇 |
2012年 | 125篇 |
2011年 | 191篇 |
2010年 | 106篇 |
2009年 | 111篇 |
2008年 | 96篇 |
2007年 | 72篇 |
2006年 | 68篇 |
2005年 | 66篇 |
2004年 | 19篇 |
2003年 | 20篇 |
2002年 | 18篇 |
2001年 | 6篇 |
2000年 | 10篇 |
1999年 | 12篇 |
1998年 | 4篇 |
1997年 | 5篇 |
1996年 | 4篇 |
1995年 | 2篇 |
1994年 | 6篇 |
1993年 | 1篇 |
1990年 | 1篇 |
1985年 | 11篇 |
1984年 | 17篇 |
1983年 | 9篇 |
1982年 | 6篇 |
1981年 | 4篇 |
1980年 | 4篇 |
1979年 | 6篇 |
1978年 | 4篇 |
排序方式: 共有1637条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
31.
Human players in our laboratory experiment received flow payoffs over 120 seconds each period from a standard Hawk–Dove bimatrix game played in continuous time. Play converged closely to the symmetric mixed Nash equilibrium under a one-population matching protocol. When the same players were matched in a two-population protocol with the same bimatrix, they showed clear movement towards an asymmetric (and very inequitable) pure Nash equilibrium of the game. These findings support distinctive predictions of evolutionary game theory. 相似文献
32.
Several researchers have studied the productivity of public capital in Japan but most have not paid attention to the types of public infrastructure or differences in production technology between prefectures. We estimate prefectural production functions with differently aggregated public capital. Through the model selection process, we examine the types of productive public capital. The empirical results show the production technologies used and how types of productive public capital differ between prefectures. 相似文献
33.
34.
为适应经济社会发展和应对未来挑战,新加坡不断加大公共研发投入规模,同时调整公共研发投入体系。近年来,新加坡更加注重部门与统筹投入兼顾,全方位支持创新活动和关注研发与经济社会关系,并通过新设或改造公共部门实施这些变革。这些做法促进了新加坡通过公共研发投入实现国家目标,对我国当前财政科技投入从分配到协调的转变具有重要借鉴意义。我们应该:适应国家经济发展,不断调整投入重点;既要强调自由研究,也要进行科学评估;建立多环节协调机制,营造良好的创新环境. 相似文献
35.
Brian Dollery Michael A. Kortt Bligh Grant 《Economic Papers: A journal of applied economics and policy》2012,31(1):114-122
A series of national and state public inquiries into the financial sustainability of local government have demonstrated that all Australian local government jurisdictions face a daunting local infrastructure maintenance and renewal backlog. Various solutions to the problem have been advanced in the literature, including the establishment of an Australian municipal bond market to facilitate the use of private sector finance to fund the remediation of the infrastructure shortfall ( Byrnes et al., 2008 ). However, despite the conceptual attraction of this particular policy proposal, as a majority of Australian local authorities are small, with limited administrative and technical capacity, they would have great difficulty in securing access to a municipal bond market. In this paper, we consider municipal banks and bond banks as alternative institutional solutions to the Australian local government infrastructure backlog. 相似文献
36.
Nicholas Crafts 《Scottish journal of political economy》2005,52(1):54-64
The paper builds on a method proposed by Geary and Stark for estimating regional incomes in Victorian Britain. This is modified by using tax data to allocate non‐wage income across regions. The results suggest that the coefficient of variation of regional GDP per head was rising rapidly prior to World War I in similar fashion to the late 20th century such that its level in 1901 and 2001 was about the same. In both episodes of globalization there were big winners and big losers among British regions. 相似文献
37.
Data on R & D expenditures and US patenting in the world's 660 largest, technologically active firms both show a linear relation between firm size and the volume of innovative activities, despite some inconsistencies between the two measures. Technological diversity increases with firm size, but relatively weakly, especially in R & D-intensive sectors. Sectoral variations in the comparative technological advantage of large firms based in Japan, the USA and W. Europe are better explained by variations in rivalry in their home market than by variations in their size. 相似文献
38.
高校智力资本运作效率的数据包络分析 总被引:2,自引:0,他引:2
文章在综合分析高校智力资本的基本概念和主要内容的基础上,提出了用数据包络分析方法评价高校智力资本运作效率的基本思路与方法,并以8所高校在同一学科中的智力资本运作情况为算例,对数据包络分析的算法和所使用的计算工具作了说明。 相似文献
39.
Brain drain or brain bank? The impact of skilled emigration on poor-country innovation 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
The development prospects of a poor country or region depend in part on its capacity for innovation. In turn, the productivity of its innovators, whom are often concentrated around urban centers, depends on their access to technological knowledge. The emigration of highly skilled individuals weakens local knowledge networks (brain drain) but may also help remaining innovators access valuable knowledge accumulated abroad (brain bank). We develop a model in which the size of the optimal innovator Diaspora depends on the competing strengths of co-location and Diaspora effects for accessing knowledge. Then, using patent citation data associated with inventions from India, we estimate the key co-location and Diaspora parameters. The net effect of innovator emigration is to harm domestic knowledge access, on average. However, knowledge access conferred by the Diaspora is particularly valuable in the production of India’s most important inventions as measured by citations received. Thus, our findings imply that the optimal emigration level may depend, at least partly, on the relative value resulting from the most cited compared to average inventions. 相似文献
40.
Christiane Hellmanzik 《European Economic Review》2010,54(2):199-90
This paper shows that ‘location matters’ in terms of premiums on creative clusters and peak ages. The analysis is based on the 214 most prominent modern visual artists born 1850-1945 and the art clusters of Paris and New York. Auction records of the past 20 years are used to estimate the value of artworks over an artist's career. The overall cluster premium for paintings produced in Paris and New York is found to be 11% and 43%, respectively; paintings made in Paris during the First World War have a premium of 14% while those produced between 1946 and 1975 have a premium of 27%. New York offers premiums for paintings produced there for all periods after the First World War, peaking at 74% between 1946 and 1975. When decomposing this premium, we find that quality rather than quantity of artists in the location is driving the results. It is argued that artists working in a cluster location reach a peak in the age-price profile of their work significantly earlier than artists working elsewhere. 相似文献