首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   2980篇
  免费   48篇
  国内免费   6篇
财政金融   294篇
工业经济   67篇
计划管理   281篇
经济学   563篇
综合类   269篇
运输经济   9篇
旅游经济   21篇
贸易经济   837篇
农业经济   74篇
经济概况   619篇
  2024年   1篇
  2023年   21篇
  2022年   41篇
  2021年   71篇
  2020年   100篇
  2019年   74篇
  2018年   31篇
  2017年   64篇
  2016年   63篇
  2015年   59篇
  2014年   150篇
  2013年   228篇
  2012年   196篇
  2011年   305篇
  2010年   177篇
  2009年   203篇
  2008年   290篇
  2007年   288篇
  2006年   243篇
  2005年   166篇
  2004年   62篇
  2003年   62篇
  2002年   42篇
  2001年   24篇
  2000年   19篇
  1999年   14篇
  1998年   9篇
  1997年   10篇
  1996年   5篇
  1995年   5篇
  1994年   4篇
  1991年   1篇
  1989年   1篇
  1985年   1篇
  1984年   2篇
  1982年   2篇
排序方式: 共有3034条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
191.
This paper considers the implications of relationship-specific investment within keiretsu for policies aimed at opening the Japanese market for intermediate goods, such as auto-parts. Both VIEs applied to parts and VERs restricting Japanese exports of autos cause the keiretsu to import a wider range of parts, but of a relatively unimportant type, such as seat covers. Since keiretsu investment and output fall, the total value of US parts exports may actually fall. For a given value of these exports, a VIE is less costly for US consumers and Japanese producers, but a VER is preferred by US automakers.  相似文献   
192.
战后许多发展中国家向现代经济增长的过渡,尤其是东亚国家和地区的发展经验均不同程度地表明:贸易对经济增长收敛有着重要的影响。对此,本文从理论上总结了贸易影响经济增长收敛的机制,同时综述了贸易影响经济增长收敛的各种实证检验,结论表明,在适当的条件下,贸易的确有助于促进贸易国的经济增长收敛。  相似文献   
193.
海峡两岸经济发展与经贸合作趋势   总被引:25,自引:0,他引:25  
祖国大陆具有发展劳动力密集型产业的比较优势,其经济发展会促进周边地区的产业结构向资本与技术密集型转变,提高包括台湾地区在内的整个东亚地区的贸易增长潜力。祖国大陆将成为台湾地区产业转移的首选地。台湾地区经济可能保持较长时期的高速增长,条件之一是推进海峡两岸经贸交流与合作,利用祖国大陆丰富的劳动力资源和巨大的市场。  相似文献   
194.
现代贸易方式不仅导致贸易利益在全球价值链上进行分配,还带来了贸易隐含污染排放在全球贸易网络中的分布。两国之间的贸易利益分配除了表现为贸易经济福利的分配,还表现为贸易隐含碳福利的分配。本文将贸易增加值分解法结合MRIO模型对2000—2014年中美双边工业品贸易增加值所隐含的碳福利分配及影响机制展开深入分析。研究结果表明:(1)在中美双边工业品增加值贸易隐含碳福利分配中,碳福利逆差在中国,碳福利顺差在美国;(2)中美工业品贸易碳福利级差经历了“先扩大,后收窄”的过程,美国次贷危机之后双边碳福利不平衡状况重新呈现扩大趋势;(3)中国碳排放强度下降、价值链地位提升以及对美进口规模扩大都有助于改善碳福利逆差的局面,但美国对中国不断扩大的中间品和最终品需求以及双边复杂的技术关联结构仍是中国碳福利逆差的主导因素;(4)全球价值链的深化可能将导致对出口国加征关税会通过降低进口消费侧排放的方式恶化加征国的贸易隐含碳福利。本文研究的时间范围同时覆盖中国加入WTO以及美国次贷危机两个重要节点,这对于重新审视中美经贸关系新格局下双边贸易隐含碳福利分配构建了一个新的分析视角,为中美未来贸易谈判以及全球碳排放责任认定提供了一个新的解读方向。  相似文献   
195.
平潭综合实验区与台湾自由经济示范区对接合作有助于推进两岸区域共赢发展,也是新时期两岸推进自由贸易区合作发展的探索实践。平潭综合实验区要在基于双方互补发展的前提下,突出平潭在两岸关系中的特殊地位,拟定"点对点"对接合作战略和对接合作重点,推行积极有效策略与措施,打造平潭开放开发新优势。  相似文献   
196.
China launched the Shanghai Free Trade Zone (FTZ) Program on September 29, 2013 in a bid to reduce administrative interventions, ease restrictions on investments, further open up its financial system, and internationalize its currency to booster shipping, logistics, and commerce. This article aims to present a background of the Shanghai FTZ and some reflections on it. China’s economic reconstruction has made a major impact on its port cities. Competitions between ports are gradually evolving into competitions between supply chains, with ports no longer considered as isolated links in the transport chain but rather as integral links in the supply chain. Ports are transitioning into fourth-generation ports with the establishment of logistics and value-added activities, which are developed in conjunction with local industrial and service businesses. In this trend, China’s port cities can provide a wide range of value-added services and become centers of commodity flow, capital flow, and information flow. Specifically, the combined effects of driving the development of peripheral industries and actively coordinating the activities of relevant parties help regulate the operations of the entire supply chain to obtain potential value-added benefits. The implementation of the Shanghai FTZ will not only stimulate trade but will also bring increased shipping and finance opportunities to the city. With free trade as the new direction and focus of the country’s economic initiatives, the Shanghai FTZ will hopefully lay the groundwork for a new round of reforms and restructuring of the Chinese economy.  相似文献   
197.
The most prominent exception to the cardinal ‘most favoured nation’ principle of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) of 1947 is in its Article XXIV relating to Customs Unions (CUs) and Free Trade Areas (FTAs). This article required, first, the general incidence of the duties and regulations of commerce imposed by members of the CU with respect to trade with non-members shall not on the whole be higher or more restrictive than those that were applicable prior to the formation of CU or FTA, and, second, that substantially all the trade among members be free. Neither requirement was very operational, because the phrases ‘general incidence’ and ‘substantially all’ being difficult legal concepts to apply. The agreement of 1994 establishing the World Trade Organization (WTO) has made ‘general incidence’ precise by defining it import-weighted average of height of barriers but without offering any rationale for the definition. Now that preferential trading arrangements such as FTAs are proliferating, reform of Article XXIV is of importance. This paper describes alternative approaches to the central question of common external tariffs of a CU. Taking off from the work of Kemp and Wan who showed the existence of a common external tariff of CU that keeps the welfare of non-members unchanged while revising that of the CU as compared to the situation prior to the formation of CU, it characterizes such a tariff structure for two leading benchmark examples as consumption-weighted average of pre-union tariffs and subsidies in the member countries.  相似文献   
198.
加入世贸组织 ,将对我国国有商业银行的银行业务、优质客户、人力资源和资产质量造成严重的冲击 ,为此 ,国有商业银行必须采取五个方面的对策 :增强银行实力、开展业务创新、提高服务质量、完善人力资源管理制度和加强资产质量管理。  相似文献   
199.
We present a two-sector model to depict the determination of trade preference. The model highlights lobby as a rivalry between sectors in competition for resources where the outcome of the lobby race is determined by each sector’s ability to generate rent at a given welfare cost to the general population. We investigate the relation between the structure of trade protection and the resource endowment.  相似文献   
200.
Using a comparative-static general equilibrium model in the context of the Western Hemisphere, this paper compares the economic effects of a “hub-and-spokes” type of bilateral trade configuration (with Chile being the hub) with those of a more comprehensive regional FTA (namely, the FTAA). The model is augmented to account for the possibility of technology spillovers and its effective assimilation among participating economies. In particular, absorptive capacity, governance factor, proximity and socio-institutional congruence conjointly determine an economy’s capacity to capture the technology that is transmitted from the developed spoke United States to other regions. JEL no. D58, F13, O33  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号