全文获取类型
收费全文 | 1953篇 |
免费 | 26篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 405篇 |
工业经济 | 98篇 |
计划管理 | 330篇 |
经济学 | 623篇 |
综合类 | 91篇 |
运输经济 | 43篇 |
旅游经济 | 19篇 |
贸易经济 | 142篇 |
农业经济 | 57篇 |
经济概况 | 171篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 22篇 |
2022年 | 31篇 |
2021年 | 59篇 |
2020年 | 85篇 |
2019年 | 46篇 |
2018年 | 36篇 |
2017年 | 75篇 |
2016年 | 71篇 |
2015年 | 49篇 |
2014年 | 107篇 |
2013年 | 193篇 |
2012年 | 105篇 |
2011年 | 154篇 |
2010年 | 80篇 |
2009年 | 112篇 |
2008年 | 159篇 |
2007年 | 128篇 |
2006年 | 138篇 |
2005年 | 74篇 |
2004年 | 69篇 |
2003年 | 48篇 |
2002年 | 26篇 |
2001年 | 33篇 |
2000年 | 13篇 |
1999年 | 21篇 |
1998年 | 14篇 |
1997年 | 5篇 |
1996年 | 4篇 |
1995年 | 5篇 |
1994年 | 4篇 |
1993年 | 2篇 |
1992年 | 3篇 |
1990年 | 1篇 |
1988年 | 1篇 |
1987年 | 2篇 |
1985年 | 1篇 |
1983年 | 1篇 |
1982年 | 1篇 |
1981年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有1979条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
101.
Victor Ginsburgh Patrick Legros Nicolas Sahuguet 《International Journal of Industrial Organization》2010,28(6):639-644
We analyze the welfare consequences of an increase in the commissions charged by intermediaries in auction markets. Commissions are similar to taxes imposed on buyers and sellers, and standard economics suggests that both sellers and buyers are made worse off by the tax. However, we show that when the buyers' participation constraint binds and when sellers set optimal reservation prices, the level of commissions correlates to participation and reservation prices in such a way that participating buyers strictly gain from higher commissions. 相似文献
102.
物流业是天津市重点发展的支柱型产业.本文旨在介绍天津物流业的现状,并对物流产业水平进行系统的统计分析,为宏观物流政策的制定提供依据. 相似文献
103.
I study a revenue-neutral reform of the U.S. income tax and welfare system that involves the adoption of a Negative Income Tax (NIT). The reform is undertaken in a life-cycle economy with individual heterogeneity and uninsurable idiosyncratic labor risk. The optimal NIT consists of a 22% rate and a transfer equivalent to 11% of per-capita GDP. The ex-ante average welfare gain is a 2.1% annual increase of individual consumption. I show that a NIT outperforms a flat tax reform (income tax plus deduction) by a considerable margin. The key consequence of the reform is that high-productivity agents increase their relative importance in the labor supply at the expense of low-productivity agents. 相似文献
104.
105.
作业成本法与传统成本计算方法的异同 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
张祎 《山西经济管理干部学院学报》2002,10(1):39-40
作业成本法源于西方发达国家,是一种新兴的成本计算方法,它与传统成本计算方法既有联系又有区别。本先从三个方面分析了二的相同之处,进而又从四个方面较为详尽地阐述了二的不同之处,通过这些对比分析,旨在揭示作业成本法是一种适应现代企业机器化生产的、科学的,先进的成本计算方法。 相似文献
106.
学术界迄今为止缺乏权威、公认的人力资源个人价值评估方法。本文以成都思盈科技有限公司作为实证样本,基于岗位相对权重与岗位绩效评估值,提出贡献价值系数这一指标,设计了一种新型的人力资源个人价值评估模型——贡献价值系数法。 相似文献
107.
现代商业银行经营竞争日趋激烈,产品品种层出不穷,盈利模式日新月异,迫切需要精确的成本信息来确定产品的真实盈利情况.然而,我国商业银行大都还采用传统的成本核算方法,核算出的银行产品成本是不完全的.为给银行管理决策提供更完全的相关信息,我国商业银行应使用作业成本法.就我国商业银行作业成本法的应用及须注意的问题作初浅探讨,希望对商业银行应用作业成本法有一定的参考. 相似文献
108.
This paper reports the results of a stated preference study that estimates the economic value for cleaning up acid rock drainage in Colorado's Snake River watershed. In contrast to much of the existing literature, the present study emphasizes benefit estimation for three implementing projects rather than benefit estimation for general changes in water quality or large scale water quality policy. The focus on implementing projects delivers information that is specifically relevant to current decisions being faced in the watershed. While valuation questions in most stated preference studies present costs that have no relation to actual project costs, this study presents a new cost share approach. Project costs are estimated and then valuation questions present different local cost shares to subjects. This approach facilitates stated cost variation necessary for estimating the mean of the distribution of project values without resorting to experimentally designed, fictitious stated costs. In addition to estimating the mean value, which facilitates benefit cost analysis, the study also provides median value estimates, which provide insights into the political feasibility of these projects. Study results suggest that local cost shares on the order of 20%-40%, depending on the project, are politically feasible. 相似文献
109.
We develop a simple two-region, cobweb-type dynamic partial equilibrium model to demonstrate the existence of optimal, possibly non-zero, trade barriers. A pure comparative statics analysis of our model suggests that a reduction of trade barriers, modeled as small but positive import tariffs, always enhances welfare. However, taking a dynamic perspective reveals that nonlinear trade interactions between two regions may generate endogenous price fluctuations which can hamper welfare. Finally, we allow special interest groups, such as consumers or producers from these two regions, to lobby for a particular level of trade barriers. Our model predicts that time-varying trade barriers may be another channel for market instability. 相似文献
110.
Brian G. Feagan Chris M. Kozma Terra L. Slaton William H. Olson 《Journal of medical economics》2014,17(12):872-880
Objective:The objective for the research was to evaluate the direct healthcare costs for Crohn’s disease (CD) patients categorized by adherence status.Methods:Adult patients with ≥1 claim for infliximab and ≥2 claims for CD who were continuously insured for 12 months before and after their first infliximab infusion (index date) were identified in a 2006–2009 US managed care database. Patients were excluded if they had rheumatoid arthritis claims, received infliximab billed as a pharmacy benefit, or received another biologic drug. Patients were categorized as being either adherent or intermittently adherent to infliximab using a pre-defined algorithm. Total and component direct costs, CD-related costs, rates of surgery, and days of hospitalization were estimated for the 360-day post-index period. Propensity weighted generalized linear models were used to adjust the cost estimates for potential confounding variables.Results:The total propensity weighted cost for infliximab adherent patients was $40,425 (95% CI?=?[$38,686, $42,242]), compared to $41,082 (95% CI?=?[$38,163, $44,223]) for the intermittently adherent (p?=?0.71). However, adherent patients had lower total direct medical costs, exclusive of infliximab, that were $13,097 (95% CI?=?[$12,141, $14,127]) compared with $20,068 (95% CI?=?[$17,676, $22,784]) for intermittently adherent patients as a result of substantially lower hospital and outpatient costs (p?0.0001).Conclusions:Greater drug-related costs for infliximab adherent patients were offset by lower costs from hospitalization and outpatient visits. These findings indicate that adherent patients have improved clinical outcomes, at a similar aggregate cost, than patients who are only intermittently adherent to therapy. 相似文献