全文获取类型
收费全文 | 9301篇 |
免费 | 347篇 |
国内免费 | 47篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 723篇 |
工业经济 | 362篇 |
计划管理 | 1080篇 |
经济学 | 3128篇 |
综合类 | 1319篇 |
运输经济 | 54篇 |
旅游经济 | 90篇 |
贸易经济 | 1125篇 |
农业经济 | 375篇 |
经济概况 | 1438篇 |
信息产业经济 | 1篇 |
出版年
2025年 | 16篇 |
2024年 | 69篇 |
2023年 | 113篇 |
2022年 | 102篇 |
2021年 | 188篇 |
2020年 | 285篇 |
2019年 | 302篇 |
2018年 | 239篇 |
2017年 | 322篇 |
2016年 | 333篇 |
2015年 | 338篇 |
2014年 | 499篇 |
2013年 | 823篇 |
2012年 | 753篇 |
2011年 | 841篇 |
2010年 | 618篇 |
2009年 | 631篇 |
2008年 | 741篇 |
2007年 | 625篇 |
2006年 | 536篇 |
2005年 | 348篇 |
2004年 | 250篇 |
2003年 | 176篇 |
2002年 | 134篇 |
2001年 | 97篇 |
2000年 | 70篇 |
1999年 | 64篇 |
1998年 | 38篇 |
1997年 | 48篇 |
1996年 | 35篇 |
1995年 | 16篇 |
1994年 | 14篇 |
1993年 | 7篇 |
1992年 | 6篇 |
1991年 | 2篇 |
1988年 | 1篇 |
1986年 | 1篇 |
1985年 | 5篇 |
1984年 | 2篇 |
1983年 | 5篇 |
1981年 | 2篇 |
排序方式: 共有9695条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
71.
Markus Lampe 《European Journal of the History of Economic Thought》2019,26(4):659-697
AbstractThe idea of “Smithian growth” rests on a “natural” development out of agriculture through capital accumulation, and the division of labour. We confront these concepts with an “historical experiment” and the case of Danish agriculture in the nineteenth century. Specifically, we look at how accounting was used to promote specialization, ultimately in butter production, leading to the massive increases in productivity that Smith predicted. We also observe the emergence of Smithian “philosophers”. This ultimately led to the capital-intensive industrialization of Danish agriculture through butter factories, and general development. We argue that this establishes the historical relevance of Smith’s theories. 相似文献
72.
信贷约束、再分配及不平等对增长的影响 总被引:2,自引:0,他引:2
当信贷对那些禀赋较少的当事人是完全可获取时,再分配对长期增长无影响.当信贷不可得时,再分配可以促进经济增长.富人与穷人之间的不平等程度越高,越容易刺激穷人掠夺富人的财富,并牺牲了总的投资与增长.恰当的再分配政策设计可以有利于禀赋少者并促进总的产出,并使社会朝着增长与和谐的方向努力. 相似文献
73.
Should government subsidize R&D and does it matter how these subsidies are allocated? We examine these questions in a dynamic model where R&D is described as sequential sampling from a distribution of new ideas. Successful discoveries affect future available resources and incentives for further R&D. Consequently, there may be under-investment in R&D. We study the effect of government interventions aimed at fostering growth through R&D. Calibrating the model with aggregate data from the Israeli business sector allows us to quantitatively compare two forms of support resembling those actually used to encourage R&D in the Israeli business sector: (i) an unrestricted subsidy that may be used at the recipients' discretion to finance R&D or other investments, (ii) a subsidy earmarked by the government for R&D activities only. While there is no theoretical way to determine which of the two subsidies will have a greater impact on search for new ideas and growth, we find that in the calibrated economy both subsidies have a significant but similar impact on the economy's output and TFP growth rates. Accordingly, in the case of the Israeli business sector, the incentives to conduct R&D were sufficiently strong, and no R&D-specific encouragement was needed. However, a sensitivity analysis reveals that for economies characterized by other parameter values this result may not be true. Correspondence to: B. Bental 相似文献
74.
75.
Tim Kelsall 《New Political Economy》2013,18(5):677-682
This contribution summarises research conducted by the Africa Power and Politics Programme, which finds that contrary to standard policy advice, neo-patrimonial governance can under certain conditions be compatible with a growth-enhancing investment climate. 相似文献
76.
《Research in Economics》2014,68(2):112-116
We show that the simple Aghion–Howitt model exhibits oscillatory indeterminacy in the process of creative destruction as firms undertaking new research do not internalize their effect on existing firms. A simple calibration shows that indeterminacy occurs for quite plausible parametrizations of the share of the intermediate good. 相似文献
77.
《Research in Economics》2014,68(2):117-132
We examine human capital's contribution to economy-wide technological progress through two channels – imitation and innovation – innovation being more skill-intensive than imitation. We develop a growth model based on the endogenous ability-driven skill acquisition decision of an individual. It is shown that skilled human capital is growth enhancing in the “imitation-innovation” regime and in the “innovation-only” regime whereas unskilled human capital is growth enhancing in the “imitation-only” regime. Steady state exists and, in the long run, the economy converges to the world technology frontier. In the diversified regime, technological progress raises the return to ability and generates an increase in wage inequality between and within groups – consistent with the pattern observed across countries. 相似文献
78.
This paper investigates whether differences between private and social returns to education of government sector employees can contribute to an explanation of the “micro–macro paradox” in the literature on education and growth. We hypothesize that in India educated people find privately rewarding jobs in a sector in which social returns are low, namely the government sector. This could help explain high returns to education at the micro level and small or negative coefficients on education growth in growth regressions at the macro level. The empirical results, which are consistent with this hypothesis, are based on an analysis of state-level data from India spanning 40 years. 相似文献
79.
Vasilios Plakandaras Rangan Gupta Periklis Gogas Theophilos Papadimitriou 《Applied economics letters》2018,25(14):1029-1033
In this article, we evaluate the causal relationship between macroeconomic uncertainty indices, inflation and growth rate for 17 Eurozone countries on a county-level examination. In performing a series of linear and nonlinear causality tests, we find little evidence of a causal relationship between uncertainty and macroeconomic variables. Thus, macroeconomic analysis based on uncertainty indices should be treated with caution. 相似文献
80.
This article shows that mark‐ups are significantly higher in South African manufacturing industries than they are in corresponding industries worldwide. We test for the consequences of this low‐level of product market competition on productivity growth. The results of the paper are that high mark‐ups have a large negative impact on productivity growth in South African manufacturing industry. Our results are robust to three different data sources, two alternative measures of productivity growth, and three distinct measures of the mark‐up. Controlling for potential endogeneity of regressors does not eliminate the findings. 相似文献