首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   2871篇
  免费   98篇
  国内免费   29篇
财政金融   988篇
工业经济   140篇
计划管理   409篇
经济学   447篇
综合类   174篇
运输经济   52篇
旅游经济   42篇
贸易经济   483篇
农业经济   90篇
经济概况   173篇
  2024年   3篇
  2023年   48篇
  2022年   39篇
  2021年   73篇
  2020年   111篇
  2019年   84篇
  2018年   85篇
  2017年   113篇
  2016年   98篇
  2015年   87篇
  2014年   155篇
  2013年   311篇
  2012年   137篇
  2011年   137篇
  2010年   138篇
  2009年   154篇
  2008年   171篇
  2007年   155篇
  2006年   174篇
  2005年   147篇
  2004年   112篇
  2003年   90篇
  2002年   60篇
  2001年   56篇
  2000年   59篇
  1999年   42篇
  1998年   32篇
  1997年   37篇
  1996年   21篇
  1995年   15篇
  1994年   13篇
  1993年   6篇
  1992年   6篇
  1991年   11篇
  1990年   5篇
  1989年   2篇
  1988年   1篇
  1987年   1篇
  1985年   1篇
  1984年   4篇
  1983年   2篇
  1982年   1篇
  1981年   1篇
排序方式: 共有2998条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
71.
我国稀土定价权的缺失与对策建议   总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1  
黄继炜 《改革与战略》2011,27(12):36-38,107
稀土是现代工业的重要基础原料,我国是世界最大的稀土储藏国,同时也是最大的稀土生产国和出口国,但在稀土价格上的决定权却很小。供大于求、产业集中度过低等是我国稀土定价权缺失的重要原因,造成大量国际贸易利益的损失。近年来,我国采取了许多稀土产业政策,取得了一定的效果。在此基础上,文章对稀土定价权的夺回提出了适度调整出口调控的手段、积极推进稀土产业的整合、不断延伸稀土产业链、大幅度提高稀土生产成本等建议。  相似文献   
72.
Interest rate dynamic effect on stock returns is examined under different levels of central bank transparency under an asset pricing context. Using a large set of emerging countries in a panel data framework, we provide evidence for a negative link between stock returns and interest rate differences. However, this negative effect is reduced significantly under a transparent central bank, underlying a non-linear impact on stock returns. Our study is focused on a period from 1998 to 2008 where fundamental changes in the level of central banks’ transparency were occurred. Our findings imply that restrictive monetary policies under high levels of transparency lead to smoother reductions on stock returns with significant benefits for financial stability.  相似文献   
73.
This study provides comprehensive evidence on the pricing of financial constraints (FC) risk on London Stock Exchange during the period 1988–2013. Utilizing a large number of proxies for FC, we find that investors are not compensated with higher premia for holding shares of financially constrained firms. To the contrary, in most of the cases, the most constrained firms significantly underperform, both statistically and economically, the least constrained ones. Focussing on the Whited–Wu index to construct a zero-cost FC factor that goes long the most constrained firms and sells short the least constrained ones, we find that this factor carries a significantly negative premium and it is priced in the cross-section over and above the commonly used risk factors.  相似文献   
74.
Lin Zhao 《Quantitative Finance》2017,17(11):1759-1782
We apply utility indifference pricing to solve a contingent claim problem, valuing a connected pair of gas fields where the underlying process is not standard Geometric Brownian Motion and the assumption of complete markets is not fulfilled. First, empirical data are often characterized by time-varying volatility and fat tails; therefore, we use Gaussian generalized autoregressive score (GAS) and GARCH models, extending them to Student’s t-GARCH and t-GAS. Second, an important risk (reservoir size) is not hedgeable. As a result, markets are incomplete which makes preference free pricing impossible and thus standard option pricing methodology inapplicable. Therefore, we parametrize the investor’s risk preference and use utility indifference pricing techniques. We use Least Squares Monte Carlo simulations as a dimension reduction technique in solving the resulting stochastic dynamic programming problems. Moreover, an investor often only has an approximate idea of the true probabilistic model underlying variables, making model ambiguity a relevant problem. We show empirically how model ambiguity affects project values, and importantly, how option values change as model ambiguity gets resolved in later phases of the projects. We show that traditional valuation approaches will consistently underestimate the value of project flexibility and in general lead to overly conservative investment decisions in the presence of time-dependent stochastic structures.  相似文献   
75.
The paper analyses the optimal pricing of the product quality scheme when concerns for relative standing exist among consumers. We demonstrate that if the proportion of high‐value consumers is over (respectively, under) 1/2 of the total consumers, a firm has an incentive to select a large (respectively, small) quality gap among products. Therefore, there exists a cut‐off level for status concerns, which eliminates quality differences, and the firm assigns the same quality to all the consumers. These results indicate that consumers’ qualities will reflect distortions at the top and bottom. Accordingly, the firm's profit depends on which consumer category is larger.  相似文献   
76.
In this paper, I investigate the competitive and welfare effects of the improvements in information accuracy in markets where firms can price discriminate after observing a private and noisy signal about a consumer's brand preference. I show that when firms believe that consumers have a brand preference for them, then they charge more to these consumers, and this price has an inverse U‐shaped relationship with the signal's accuracy. In contrast, the price charged after a disloyal signal has been observed falls as the signal's accuracy rises. While industry profit and overall welfare fall monotonically when price discrimination is based on increasingly more accurate information, the reverse happens to consumer surplus.  相似文献   
77.
We study the role of brand capital – a primary form of intangible capital – for firm valuation and risk in the cross section of publicly traded firms. Using an empirical measure of brand capital stock constructed from advertising expenditures accounting data, we show that: (i) firms with low brand capital investment rates have higher average stock returns than firms with high brand capital investment rates, a difference of 5.2% per annum; (ii) more brand capital intensive firms have higher average stock returns than less brand capital intensive firms, a difference of 5.1% per annum; and (iii) investment in both brand capital and physical capital is volatile and procyclical. A neoclassical investment-based model in which brand capital is a factor of production subject to adjustment costs matches the data well. The model also provides a novel explanation for the empirical links between advertising expenditures and stock returns around seasoned equity offerings (SEO) documented in previous studies.  相似文献   
78.
79.
We study a production economy with regime switching in the conditional mean and volatility of productivity growth. The representative agent has generalized disappointment aversion (GDA) preferences. We show that volatility risk in productivity growth carries a positive and sizable risk premium in levered equity. Our model can endogenously generate long-run risks in the volatility of consumption growth observed in the data. We show that introducing leverage with a procyclical dividend process consistent with the data is critical for the GDA preferences to have a large impact on equity returns.  相似文献   
80.
夏睿 《改革与战略》2014,(5):134-136
自从中国加入世贸组织以来,我国大豆对外贸易逆差越来越大。大豆进口量逐年增长以及对进口依存度过高等现象的存在,给国内大豆种植生产带来了一定的影响。文章主要从中国大豆对外贸易的现状着手,分别从中国大豆定价权的缺失、转基因大豆对我国大豆行业的冲击、国内政策对大豆产业的支持力度不够、大豆进口管理机制有待完善等四个方面阐述了中国大豆对外贸易所存在的问题。  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号