首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   10014篇
  免费   397篇
  国内免费   154篇
财政金融   506篇
工业经济   279篇
计划管理   1045篇
经济学   1979篇
综合类   1446篇
运输经济   19篇
旅游经济   38篇
贸易经济   3035篇
农业经济   556篇
经济概况   1662篇
  2024年   18篇
  2023年   113篇
  2022年   110篇
  2021年   188篇
  2020年   339篇
  2019年   245篇
  2018年   236篇
  2017年   209篇
  2016年   213篇
  2015年   263篇
  2014年   474篇
  2013年   957篇
  2012年   786篇
  2011年   943篇
  2010年   653篇
  2009年   695篇
  2008年   940篇
  2007年   811篇
  2006年   743篇
  2005年   521篇
  2004年   326篇
  2003年   231篇
  2002年   131篇
  2001年   121篇
  2000年   81篇
  1999年   44篇
  1998年   34篇
  1997年   30篇
  1996年   27篇
  1995年   14篇
  1994年   20篇
  1993年   5篇
  1992年   8篇
  1991年   7篇
  1990年   4篇
  1989年   3篇
  1986年   1篇
  1985年   5篇
  1984年   4篇
  1983年   9篇
  1982年   2篇
  1980年   1篇
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 125 毫秒
21.
对外贸易的拉动作用是实现我国十六大经济增长目标的重要保证。但是,反观当前的国内外环境,我国进出口贸易的发展遇到了诸多困难。欲解决这些问题,必须进行制度创新,其中培育城市群是一种可行的办法。而环渤海区域以其特有优势,成为培育对外贸易城市群的首选。为此,我国需要在环渤海区域大力发展高新技术产业,培育产业集群,引导民营企业发展,以及发挥政府的政策作用。  相似文献   
22.
现实中的国际贸易不是自由贸易,国际贸易体制中一直都是自由贸易和贸易保护同时并存,以1GATT/WTO也不是自由贸易组织。管理贸易是指介于纯粹自由贸易和完全贸易保护之间的各种情形,其特点是规则导向、有较大兼容性以及可塑性。管理贸易的发展可以有两个完全相反的方向,而GATT/WTO倡导的贸易自由化实质上是在自由贸易和贸易保护两种成分并存的国际贸易体制中抑制贸易保护、提高贸易自由的程度。  相似文献   
23.
世界经济一体化与商业银行发展   总被引:2,自引:0,他引:2  
随着各个国家经济联系范围不断扩大及各国对外经济准入政策的放宽 ,加之信息技术、网络技术的发展 ,使各国经济融入世界范围的经济一体化格局。国际资本流动速度加快、范围扩大和国际贸易的飞速发展 ,既是世界经济一体化的必然结果 ,也是促进世界经济一体化的重要因素。而这些相互关联的各个方面又同时对各国的银行业产生巨大的影响。本文通过分析当前世界经济一体化的格局、国际贸易的发展状况及国际资本流动趋势 ,研究在此基础上我国商业银行发展面临的机遇和挑战以及应对措施  相似文献   
24.
We argue that when individuals care about their consumption relative to that of their neighbours, a home bias emerges, that is investors overweight domestic stocks in their portfolios. Domestic stocks are preferred because they also serve the objective of mimicking the economic fortunes and welfare of the investor's neighbours, countrymen, and social reference group. We also demonstrate that globalization mitigates the home bias, and derive a modified international CAPM.  相似文献   
25.
Do incentives differ between large and small organizations? Results from a representative survey of compensation managers are used to shed light on the issues. I find that (i) small establishments rely less on pecuniary incentives, and have a significantly more hostile attitude towards incentive schemes based on competition and relative rewards; (ii) large units are more vulnerable to mechanisms of efficiency wages, effects that remain even after controlling for differences in monitoring ability; (iii) large units are more prone to indicate that negative reciprocity is important, and that their employees care about relative pay. I argue that these findings fit with behavioral stories of incentives and motivation, in particular those stressing group interaction effects, inequity aversion and gift exchange.  相似文献   
26.
In this paper, we present a two-country trade model with external economies of scale that emerge on an international level but are partially localized in each country. First, we show that the larger country exports the good produced in an industry with external economies of scale in the trading equilibrium. Second, we investigate the welfare effects of trade for the following two cases: (I) the case where external economies are completely localized in autarky; (II) the case where external economies are internationally effective in autarky. In case (II), it is shown that trade can be welfare-decreasing for both countries.  相似文献   
27.
The comparison of true cost of living indices between demographically different households (relative equivalence scale) is argued to be sensitive to the way demographic characteristics enter demand analysis. In particular, parameters reflecting the cost of demographic characteristics at base prices, though themselves do not have welfare (equivalence scale) interpretation, can alter the benchmark from which demographically varying inflation effects are measured. The empirical analysis, based on a rank‐3 demand system applied to UK individual household data, shows that the inflation adjustment of child benefits can vary with the way demographic costs at base period prices are specified.  相似文献   
28.
This paper revisits the relationship between a country’s openness and its per capita income. Building on Frankel and Romer, it argues that a dynamic econometric specification similar to the ones used in empirical growth studies better fits the theoretical literature and also resolves some otherwise unresolved inconsistencies. The preferred econometric method is Blundell and Bond’s system-GMM estimator, which allows dealing with measurement error, weak instruments, and time-invariant country-specific effects. The findings confirm the existence of a strong effect of trade on income but fail to find evidence for trade as an independent factor of divergence. JEL no. F43, O40  相似文献   
29.
如何看待我国民营上市公司EVA与MVA的反差问题   总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1  
张磊 《商业研究》2004,(4):107-109
通过对2001年EVA与MVA反差最大的20家民营企业的统计数据进行了相关分析与因子分析,提出使用第一主成分作为投机炒作的度量,弟二主成分反映了股本与业绩的背离程度,并对2001年EVA与MVA反差最大的20家企业进行分析并排序。  相似文献   
30.
This paper examines a two-country, dynamic game model of pollution control in the presence of economic interactions between countries within a period, as well as the environmental interaction between periods (i.e., a change in the stock of global pollution). These economic interactions emerge because of changes in the terms of trade of polluting goods or the market share of domestic polluting industries. It is shown that if within-period externalities exist, a noncooperative equilibrium may result in a smaller stock of global pollution in the steady state than does international cooperation. Moreover, the properties of equilibrium paths depend on the direction and size of such externalities. In addition, trigger strategy equilibria that achieve the outcome of the collusive solution are examined.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号