首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   185篇
  免费   2篇
  国内免费   2篇
财政金融   11篇
工业经济   1篇
计划管理   41篇
经济学   57篇
综合类   28篇
运输经济   1篇
贸易经济   18篇
农业经济   4篇
经济概况   12篇
水利工程   16篇
  2025年   1篇
  2023年   1篇
  2021年   1篇
  2020年   4篇
  2019年   2篇
  2018年   5篇
  2017年   5篇
  2016年   5篇
  2015年   5篇
  2014年   6篇
  2013年   12篇
  2012年   18篇
  2011年   15篇
  2010年   9篇
  2009年   14篇
  2008年   14篇
  2007年   4篇
  2006年   9篇
  2005年   13篇
  2004年   5篇
  2003年   7篇
  2002年   8篇
  2001年   6篇
  2000年   6篇
  1999年   5篇
  1998年   2篇
  1997年   1篇
  1996年   2篇
  1995年   1篇
  1994年   1篇
  1993年   1篇
  1976年   1篇
排序方式: 共有189条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
21.
目前针对火灾、泥石流等突发性事件引起的生态公益林的毁坏,许多省份给予每亩500—700元的定额赔偿金,并且保险定价有一定的随意性。由于林改后对生态公益林的补贴一般每亩只有10—20元,相对于保险赔偿金则过低,如此便产生了生态公益林保险的变相融资道德风险倾向,即:林农很可能为套取保险资金而消极防御火灾,甚至故意纵火。运用林农效用函数,通过确定性等价收入等理论定出生态公益林的保险价格,设计出一套实物支付与分期付款相结合的保险方案,有效地规避了此类道德风险的发生。  相似文献   
22.
In this article we analyse whether the Ricardian equivalence hypothesis is a valid approximation for Spains economic reality or whether there exist deviations from that situation which would be more in line with the conventional Keynesian perspective of the effects of debt on private consumption-savings decisions.Our aim is to contribute to the rather sparse empirical literature on the subject for the Spanish case. The analysis is based on annual aggregate data for Spain covering the years 1955 to 2000, and uses both the structural and the Euler equation approaches to test the neutrality proposition, and is thus to be considered as a generalization of foregoing work on the Spanish economy.The findings indicate that support for Ricardian equivalence is mixed, while we also find very little support for the Keynesian specification of consumption and fiscal policy.First revision received: March 2003 / Final version received: October 2003The authors wish to thank M. Ferré, J.M. González-Páramo, A. Marchante, P. Meguire, F. Pedraja, J.L. Raymond, J. Salinas and two anonymous referees for their helpful comments and suggestions on this paper. We also thank the participants in the V Encuentro de Economía Aplicada (Oviedo, Spain, June 2002) and the XVII Simposio de Análisis Económico (Salamanca, Spain, December 2002) for their comments. Any remaining defects are our responsibility. We also are grateful to the Institute for Fiscal Studies of Spain (Ministerio de Hacienda, Secretaría de Estado de Hacienda) for its financial support.  相似文献   
23.
Industry informants suggest that the equity of well-known, established brands can be leveraged to create value for unfamiliar or less-established brands. To the extent that cues in the retail environment imply some commonality between the high-equity brand and the less-established brand, benefits to the less-established brand may be expected. We refer to this implied commonality as strategic equivalence. Sharing the retail brand portfolio with high-equity brands is one way of establishing strategic equivalence. Display structure—whether the brands are displayed separately or intermixed—can also affect perceptions of strategic equivalence. In two studies, we demonstrate the ability of high-equity brands to increase the value of lower-equity brands in the same retail department and the ability of display structure to moderate this effect.  相似文献   
24.
    
This paper studies the equilibrium characterization of asset pricing in a discrete‐time Lucas exchange economy (Lucas 1978) with the intertemporal recursive utility function of Epstein and Zin (1989). A general formulation of equilibrium asset pricing is presented. It is shown that risk aversion of a certainty equivalent corresponds to risk aversion in the intertemporal asset pricing model. The discrete‐time analogue of Ma's (1993) option pricing formula is derived in an i.i.d. environment, with which we prove an observational nonequivalence theorem in distinguishing the differences of the betweenness recursive utility functions and the expected utility functions. Additionally, when the consumption growth rate follows a first-order Markov process, it is shown that the observational nonequivalence result holds for Kreps–Porteus expected utility. Finally, as by-products, this paper also contains derivations of closed-form formulas for the aggregate equity (with endogenously determined yields), the term structure of interest rates, and European call options on the aggregate equity in a Markov setting.  相似文献   
25.
This paper uses a two-country, flexible-price model with overlapping generations of infinitely lived households to study the role of net foreign asset dynamics in the propagation of productivity shocks. Absence of Ricardian equivalence ensures existence of a unique steady-state level of net foreign assets, to which the economy returns following temporary shocks. Model dynamics are significantly different from those of a setup in which terms of trade movements perform all the international adjustment and net foreign assets do not move. The difference relative to a complete markets economy in which net foreign asset movements play no role in shock transmission is smaller. It is amplified if the substitutability across goods rises and if shocks are permanent.  相似文献   
26.
    
The Ricardian equivalence hypothesis states that, under certain conditions, the decision to finance public expenditure via higher taxes or by issuance of government bonds is irrelevant for private consumption decisions. It is assumed that consumers are fully rational and aware that current and future public spending has to be eventually paid off. Thus, the present value of public expenditures reduces the consumer’s permanent income and changes in the intertemporal allocation of taxes only affect private savings, leaving consumption unaffected. On the other hand, if consumers behave in accordance with the Keynesian hypothesis, then government spending has a positive effect on private consumption. We test the validity of the Ricardian equivalence hypothesis for the Australian economy on three Euler‐type consumption functions using a new historical dataset covering the period of 1901–2007. The analysis is performed in three versions: on all available observations without and with dummy variables for WWI, the Great Depression and WWII, and on a subsample that excludes the years when those turbulent events took place. In most cases there is ample evidence against Ricardian equivalence suggesting that fiscal policy can play a stabilising role in Australia.  相似文献   
27.
28.
    
To understand how a supplier helps a buying company create value through innovations, studies have focused on a supplier's internal resources or its relationship with a buying company. Building upon this body of literature, we develop a theory of supplier network-based innovation value in this conceptual paper. This theory explains how a supplier's upstream and downstream value network can be a source of competitive advantage for a buying company. Specifically, it proposes that the levels and types of supplier innovation value is contingent on the configuration of a dual-ego value network, characterized by the locus and degree of buyer-supplier structural equivalence. This theory also explains how a supplier's ties with a buying firm's competitors can pose both opportunity and risk to buying company innovation. This theory contributes to the literature by showing when “seemingly undesirable” suppliers, due to a lack of technical capability or strong relationship with a buying company, might still be valuable to a buying company's innovation.  相似文献   
29.
Summary In this paper the intertemporal optimization approach is adopted in order to estimate an empirical version of Blanchard's (1985) overlapping generations model. The observed sluggishness in consumption is incorporated into the model by recognizing both durability and habit formation as relevant determinants of total consumption. The model is estimated using quarterly data for The Netherlands from 1969:I to 1990:IV. The empirical estimates suggest that the status of the Dutch consumer as a true Ricardian is unambiguously rejected. The results furthermore suggest that this rejection is due to the existence of both liquidity constraints and finite planning horizons.Comments by Peter Broer, Jeroen Kremers, Debora Molenaar, Rick van der Ploeg, Frans Spinnewyn, Casper de Vries, Ed Westerhout and two anonymous referees are very much appreciated. Elbert Dijkgraaf has provided invaluable research assistance. We also thank participants of the OCFEB workshop and the CES seminar at the K.U. Leuven for their comments.  相似文献   
30.
本文从人口流动的区位黏性这一全新视角,将地方政府性债务的李嘉图等价命题纳入新经济地理研究框架进行理论分析。为了进一步揭示理论模型的政策含义,采用空间计量方法验证沿海地区地方政府性债务的局部正相关特征。最优的债务政策取决于经济系统的初始条件,在非对称经济结构已经存在的情况下,单纯建设本地区的基础设施只会降低区域内的交易成本,这对于那些仅着眼于投巨资用于城市“硬件”建设的地方政府来说显然是一叶障目。建议依靠基础设施网络提高区域协同创新能力,培育规模报酬递增的专业化产业集群。  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号