全文获取类型
收费全文 | 1385篇 |
免费 | 101篇 |
国内免费 | 97篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 102篇 |
工业经济 | 61篇 |
计划管理 | 164篇 |
经济学 | 271篇 |
综合类 | 81篇 |
运输经济 | 5篇 |
旅游经济 | 12篇 |
贸易经济 | 72篇 |
农业经济 | 46篇 |
经济概况 | 102篇 |
水利工程 | 667篇 |
出版年
2024年 | 7篇 |
2023年 | 29篇 |
2022年 | 21篇 |
2021年 | 38篇 |
2020年 | 56篇 |
2019年 | 54篇 |
2018年 | 50篇 |
2017年 | 82篇 |
2016年 | 61篇 |
2015年 | 83篇 |
2014年 | 103篇 |
2013年 | 101篇 |
2012年 | 109篇 |
2011年 | 105篇 |
2010年 | 83篇 |
2009年 | 77篇 |
2008年 | 102篇 |
2007年 | 77篇 |
2006年 | 75篇 |
2005年 | 45篇 |
2004年 | 36篇 |
2003年 | 43篇 |
2002年 | 35篇 |
2001年 | 20篇 |
2000年 | 16篇 |
1999年 | 14篇 |
1998年 | 13篇 |
1997年 | 6篇 |
1996年 | 12篇 |
1995年 | 11篇 |
1994年 | 5篇 |
1993年 | 5篇 |
1992年 | 4篇 |
1991年 | 3篇 |
1989年 | 1篇 |
1986年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有1583条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
41.
42.
中国物质消耗—收入关系的理论与实际分析 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
本文先提出了一个物质消耗与收入关系的理论模型。然后,对我国及我国经济较为发达的广东省和上海市的物质消耗与国内生产总值进行实证分析。本文的结论是,目前即使是经济发达的地区,物资消耗与GDP的关系没有表现出强去物质化,而是呈正相关,但相关曲线的斜率逐渐递减。所以,我国未来的一段时间里,经济发展需要更多的物质投入,但对物质投入的依赖性将下降。 相似文献
43.
在充裕资金面的影响下,一季度银行间债券市场走出一波温和上扬行情,10年期国债收益率从年初的3.7%左右下行至一季度末的3.35%附近。文章综合相关数据分析后预计,未来工业增加值增速、货币供应量将有所放缓,新增贷款有望平稳增长,宏观经济仍将高位运行,结合经济走势相似年份的CPl均值,预计二季度CPI上行至3%后逐步回落,国债及政策性金融债收益率曲线整体小幅上行,收益率曲线呈现陡峭化态势。 相似文献
44.
当今世界,如何使自己企业的供应链能够更有效率的运作,便成为了许多管理人员继续考虑的一个问题。基于此背景下,许多供应链的优化模型被理论界提出。针对传统的模型存在一些不足之处,通过采用系统模拟的方法,提出了一套新的评价系统,应用了权衡曲线的原理,并考察了在需求发生变化的情况下决策的适应情况,给出不同情景下的决策建议。 相似文献
45.
Economic sanctions have a poor track record in achieving their objectives. In most cases, they are ineffective in bringing about policy change, cause increased suffering in the sanctioned country and reduce opportunities for business. This paper provides additional insights into why sanctions fail by examining two overlooked factors: power–dependency theory and pressure for political stability. 相似文献
46.
This paper develops a model of the relationship between public sector employment, total output and aggregate real demand
in market prices, where public employment has a positive productivity effect on private output. Public employment crowds out
private employment and output because its increase induces higher wages and taxes. The valuation of government output is also
taken into account. While public employment affects total output and aggregate real demand in an a priori ambiguous way, numerical
simulations suggest that the relationship may be nonlinear; positive, when public sector is “small” and negative, when it
is “large”. Using the annual data from 22 OECD countries over the period 1960–1996 and estimating and testing for threshold
models and more commonly used specifications with multiplicative interaction terms give support to this nonlinearity hypothesis
between public employment and private sector output.
First version received: October 1996/Final version received: April 2000 相似文献
47.
48.
Jonathan P. Caulkins Gustav FeichtingerDieter Grass Richard F. HartlPeter M. Kort 《Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control》2011,35(4):462-478
The paper considers the problem of a firm that, while producing a standard product, has the option to introduce an innovative product. The innovative product competes with the standard product and will therefore reduce revenues of the standard product. A distinction is made between innovative products that do or do not become even more relatively appealing as their market share grows (e.g., because of network externalities). It is shown that in the former case, which we call a “disruptive” good, history dependent long run equilibria can occur, which are in line with recent real life economic examples. 相似文献
49.
This study investigates how unexpected announcements in Brazilian and U.S. macroeconomic indicators affect the term structure of nominal interest rates, as well as implicit inflation expectations and real interest rates. Using daily data from March 2005 to December 2012, we employ an extended Vector Error Correction Model to take into account nonstationarity and the long-term equilibrium among different maturities of those curves. We found empirical evidence that macroeconomic surprises, domestic (Brazilian) and external (U.S. American), which lead the market to believe that there might be a higher risk of inflation or an overheated economy, raise nominal interest rates, implicit expected inflation and real interest rates. Surprisingly, in relation to the efficient-market hypothesis, we found that some macroeconomic surprises have a lagged effect on the yield curves. We also tested the impact of the global financial crisis of 2007–09 and found that the crisis affected significantly the direction and magnitude of the responses to macroeconomic news. 相似文献
50.
In this paper, we argue that the roles of public policies concerning COVID-19 can be better understood in light of the past discussions on the Great Inflation of the 1970s and the 1980s. Like the Phillips Curve in macroeconomics, the pandemic presents a trade-off between economic activities and something undesirable, which is, in this case, infection. Like the Phillips Curve, this apparent output-infection trade-off is an elusive one and it is lost in the long run. Containing infections calls for decisive policy action. This paper shows that we could design a reaction function, which sets the level of economic activity as a function of the state of infection, in such a way that the possibility of an infection explosion would be eliminated. Our empirical analysis suggests that Tokyo, New York, and London since September 2020 do not satisfy this desirable property. 相似文献