首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   648篇
  免费   38篇
  国内免费   1篇
财政金融   127篇
工业经济   37篇
计划管理   97篇
经济学   175篇
综合类   5篇
运输经济   7篇
旅游经济   5篇
贸易经济   180篇
农业经济   10篇
经济概况   37篇
邮电经济   7篇
  2023年   14篇
  2022年   13篇
  2021年   13篇
  2020年   23篇
  2019年   31篇
  2018年   38篇
  2017年   35篇
  2016年   41篇
  2015年   29篇
  2014年   37篇
  2013年   63篇
  2012年   38篇
  2011年   40篇
  2010年   27篇
  2009年   29篇
  2008年   23篇
  2007年   14篇
  2006年   13篇
  2005年   9篇
  2004年   9篇
  2003年   9篇
  2002年   5篇
  2001年   6篇
  2000年   5篇
  1999年   7篇
  1998年   3篇
  1997年   7篇
  1995年   6篇
  1994年   5篇
  1990年   4篇
  1989年   3篇
  1985年   8篇
  1984年   8篇
  1982年   3篇
  1981年   4篇
  1980年   3篇
  1979年   4篇
  1977年   3篇
  1975年   2篇
  1974年   4篇
  1973年   2篇
  1972年   2篇
  1970年   3篇
  1969年   2篇
  1967年   2篇
  1966年   2篇
  1958年   2篇
  1941年   2篇
  1932年   2篇
  1930年   2篇
排序方式: 共有687条查询结果,搜索用时 781 毫秒
1.
The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics - This paper provides new evidence on the effect of housing wealth on consumption by focusing on the impact of home-equity extraction. We develop a...  相似文献   
2.
This article investigates the relationship between a debtor country's external financial indicators and the costs associated with the insurance of export credits to that country. For this purpose a stylized model of export credit insurance (ECI) is developed, the central idea being that ECI is similar to a contingent claim such as a European put option. Thus, tools from option pricing theory were used to calculate the price of ECI, implying that not only the current financial position but also the volatility of the changes in that position determine such costs. The empirical results of a statistical analysis of the premium rates for ECI, applied by a private export credit insurer to seventy-seven developing countries during 1993, provide some support for these hypotheses. In particular, the reserves-over-imports ratio of a debtor country and the volatility of the rates of change of this ratio appear to contribute significantly to the premium rates that apply to that country. Thus, the article provides evidence that option pricing parameters do play role in practical insurance pricing, even if this pricing is not explicitly based on these parameters. Premium rates are set as if an underlying option market operated. Thus, the trade of countries with volatile external financial positions is saddled with higher costs than that of countries with more stable positions.  相似文献   
3.
4.
Flexible exchange rates as shock absorbers   总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1  
In this paper we analyze empirically the effect of terms of trade shocks on economic performance under alternative exchange rate regimes. We are particularly interested in investigating whether terms of trade disturbances have a smaller effect on growth in countries with a flexible exchange rate arrangement. We also analyze whether negative and positive terms of trade shocks have asymmetric effects on growth, and whether the magnitude of these asymmetries depends on the exchange rate regime. We find evidence suggesting that terms of trade shocks get amplified in countries that have more rigid exchange rate regimes. We also find evidence of an asymmetric response to terms of trade shocks: the output response is larger for negative than for positive shocks. Finally, we find evidence supporting the view that, after controlling for other factors, countries with more flexible exchange rate regimes grow faster than countries with fixed exchange rates.  相似文献   
5.
Zusammenfassung Das Jahresmodell WIFO-JMX, das in der vorliegenden Arbeit vorgestellt wird, ist primär ein mittelfristiges Modell. Bei seiner Spezifikation wurde daher der Angebotsseite große Aufmerksamkeit gewidmet. Wir verwenden eineCobb-Douglas Produktionsfunktion als langfristige Planungsbeziehung. Von dieser Produktionsfunktion werden dann Faktor-nachfragegleichungen für Arbeit und Kapital abgeleitet. Die Identität der Produktionsfunktionsparameter in beiden Faktornachfragefunktionen garantiert die Konsistenz der langfristigen Eigenschaften dieser Beziehungen. Weiters erlaubt diese Spezifikation Faktorsubstitution als Reaktion auf änderungen in den relativen Preisen. In einem mittelfristigen Modell sollte dieser Aspekt nicht vernachlässigt werden. Die so geschätzten Faktornachfragefunktionen wurden dann ihrerseits verwendet, um verschiedene Auslastungsmaße herzuleiten. Wir unterscheiden hier zwischen Kapazitäts-, Vollbeschäftigungs- und Potentialproduktion.Es verwundert nun nicht weiter, daß ein mittelfristiges Modell kurzfristige Konjunkturschwankungen eher ungenau abbildet. Da aber gerade kurzfristige Prognoseprobleme im Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung breiten Raum einnehmen, haben wir eine spezielle Prognoseversion von WIFO-JMX entwickelt. Diese Version ist in ihrer theoretischen Struktur wesentlich einfacher. Wir ließen hier das Produktionsfunktionskonzept fallen, was den Simultanitätsgrad des Modells beträchtlich reduzierte. Erste Tests der Treffsicherheit der mit dieser Modellversion erstellten Prognosen verliefen zurfriedenstellend.Es soll jedoch nicht verschwiegen werden, daß beide Modellversionen noch recht unvollständig sing. Der monetäre und der öffentliche Sektor fehlen zur Zeit völlig, die Zahlungsbilanz wird gegenwärtig äußerst rudimentär behandelt. Wir beabsichtigen, dieses Basismodell nun nach und nach zu einem vollständigen Gleichungssystem der österreichischen Wirtschaft auszubauen. Dabei ist uns völlig bewußt, daß der vielleicht schwierigere Teil der Arbeit noch vor uns liegt. Denn für den monetären und den öffentlichen Sektor müssen wir Ansätze entwickeln, die den von ausländischen Erfahrungen hier teilweise stark abweichenden österreichischen Gegebenheiten Rechnung tragen.  相似文献   
6.
We estimate the pro-competitive effects of Austrias participation in the Single Market after its European Union (EU) accession in 1995 in terms of firms market power as measured by the Lerner index, using a sample of 46 industries and 7 industry groups, covering the period 1978–2001. In the framework of the markup estimation method suggested by Roeger (1995), we test for both an instantaneous structural break between 1993 and 1998 and also estimate logistic smooth transition models to take up the proposition that the regime shift is likely to have occurred gradually rather than as a big bang. In sum, the results provide no reason for being euphoric: Pronounced markup reductions were only found in three industry groups (mining and quarrying, wholesale and retail trade; financial services and real estate). At the more disaggregate level, the picture is mixed: Both increases and reductions in market power have been found.  相似文献   
7.
Breuss  Fritz 《Empirica》1980,7(2):223-259
Summary Nordhaus's (1975) model of the political business cycle is extended in this paper by explicitly formulating the link between the economic sphere (represented by the Phillips curve) and fiscal policy. This extended model yields the hypothesis that during an electoral period the budgetary policy is contractionary in the first half and expansionary in the second half with the consequences of a reduction in unemployment (increase in inflation) before elections and a rise in unemployment (decrease in inflation) after elections. This hypothesis is tested against the data of the Austrian economy by a non-parametric test (which leads to a rejection of our hypothesis for Austria). The extent of the political business cycle bias is demonstrated by policy simulations within a macroeconomic model.
Zusammenfassung Das Modell vonNordhaus (1975) über den Politischen Konjunkturzyklus wird in diesem Artikel erweitert, indem explizit die Beziehung zwischen dem ökonomischen Bereich (repräsentiert durch die Phillips-Kurve) und der Fiskalpolitik hergestellt wird. Dieses erweiterte Modell führt zu der Hypothese, daß während einer Legislaturperiode die Budgetpolitik in der ersten Hälfte restriktiv und in der zweiten Hälfte expansiv ist. Als Konsequenz dieser Politik kommt es zu einer Verringerung der Arbeitslosigkeit (einem Anstieg der Inflation) vor Wahlen und einem Anstieg der Arbeitslosigkeit (einer Verringerung der Inflation) nach den Wahlen. Diese Hypothese wird an Hand österreichischer Daten mit Hilfe eines nichtparametrischen Tests geprüft (was zu einer Ablehnung unserer Hypothese für Österreich führt). Das quantitative Ausmaß des durch den Politischen Konjunkturzyklus entstehenden bias wird dann mit Hilfe von politischen Simulationen im Rahmen eines makroökonomischen Modells demonstriert.

Definitions AK Public purchases of goods and services + public investment (A.S.) - AT Unemployed persons, in total (in 1.000) - AZA Worked hours per worker (in hours) - BAU Central government's expenditures (outlays) in total (A.S.) - BEI Central government's revenues (receipts) in total (A.S.) - BS Budget deficit of the Central government (A.S.) - CB Labour supply (in 1.000) - CH Unemployment rate (%) - CON Public consumption (A.S.) - COR Public consumption (A.S. 1964) - CPN Private consumption (A.S.) - CPR Private consumption (A.S. 1964) - CUB Current balance (A.S.) - DS Direct taxes + public income from property-transfers to households + transfers from households (A.S.) - DX DS-public income from property (A.S.) - D7273 Dummy for monetary policy and Dummy for change from gross turnover tax to VAT (1972+1; 1973–1; other 0) - D7278 Dummy for investment tax (1972+1; 1973–1; 1977+1; 1978–1; other 0) - D73US Dummy for shift of employers to employees (1973+1; other 0) - D7375 Dummy for incomes tax reform (1973–1; 1975–1; other 0) - D7778 Dummy for extra VAT (1977+1; 1978–1; other 0) - EBE Population in total (in 1.000) - EET Employment in total + unemployed (total labour supply; in 1.000) - ESE Employers (in 1.000) - EUS Employees (in 1.000) - FBN Monetary base (A.S.) - FGN Money M1 (A.S.) - FG Money M1 (A.S. 1964) - GDN Gross domestic product (A.S.) - GDR Gross domestic product (A.S. 1964) - GER Energy (1.000 t/TCE) - GIR Industry output (A.S. 1964) - GE Profits in total (A.S.) - GV Profits in total (A.S. 1964) - IS Indirect taxes—transfers to firms (A.S.) - ITN Gross fixed investment (A.S.) - ITR Gross fixed investment (A.S. 1964) - JR Final domestic demand (A.S. 1964) - LA Stocks and statistical discrepancies; National account basis (A.S.) - LEAD Difference of one major party over the other in parliament in percentage points - LB Foreign balance (A.S.) - LKV Long term capital transactions (A.S.) - MA Money M1 + profits (A.S. 1964) - MMN Imports of goods and services (A.S.) - MMR Imports of goods and services (A.S. 1964) - OIN Public investment (A.S.) - OKG Public purchases of goods and services (A.S.) - PC Private consumption deflator (1964=100) - PEN Energy prices (1964=100) - PI Gross fixed investment deflator (1964=100) - PK Imports of goods and services deflator (1964=100) - PL Exports of goods and services deflator (1964=100) - PT Gross domestic product deflator (1964=100) - RES Value change in balance of payments reserves (A.S.) - RIR Interest rate for long term bonds (%) - SD Stocks and statistical discrepancies; National account basis (A.S. 1964) - ST Overall indirect taxes—subsidies; National account basis (A.S.) - STD Direct taxes (A.S.) - STI Indirect taxes (A.S.) - TAH Transfers to households (A.S.) - TBB Trade balance (A.S.) - TTT Time (1960, 1961,..., 1979) - TUN Transfers to firms (A.S.) - TVH Transfers from households (A.S.) - VW Gross fixed investment plus exports of goods and services (A.S. 1964) - WON Changes in foreign currency reserves of the National Bank (A.S.) - WKU Changes in foreign currency reserves of all commercial banks (A.S.) - WW Changes in balance of payments' official reserves (A.S.) - XB Relative energy prices (1964=100) - XXN Exports of goods and services (A.S.) - XXR Exports of goods and services (A.S. 1964) - YLN Wages and salaries (compensation of employees; A.S.) - YOB Public income from property (A.S.) - YVN Net disposable income (A.S.) - YY Net disposable income (A.S.) - YYN National income (A.S.) - ZST Statistical discrepancies in balance of payments (A.S.) - A.S billion Austrian Schilling at current prices - A.S. 1964 billion Austrian Schilling at constant prices (basis 1964)  相似文献   
8.
This paper considers a public-good economy with congestion, where participants jointly produce a public good from input of a private good. This economic model gives rise to a transferable-utility game, the profit game, that depends on consumer preferences and a congestion parameter. The simplicity of the game allows the maximum level of congestion that guarantees the nonemptiness of the core of the economy to be determined. It is known that the sustainability of the Lindahl equilibrium in the core of the economy depends on the distribution of profits. In this paper two distributions of profits are compared: the Lindahl solution and the marginal-contribution solution. The latter is more often in the core than the Lindahl solution which in turn Lorenz-dominates the marginal-contribution solution.  相似文献   
9.
We study the relationship of corporate social responsibility (CSR) and the distribution of stock returns for an international sample. Firms with a high level of CSR generally exhibit superior stock price synchronicity in the markets of Europe, Japan, and the United States. In particular, we identify optimal levels of CSR to minimize idiosyncratic risk for each region. Moreover, CSR has a mitigating effect on crash risk in Europe and the United States. In contrast, firms from the Asia‐Pacific region display CSR over‐investment followed by a higher crash risk. This appears to be a consequence of globalization, which forces firms from Asia‐Pacific to overinvest in CSR to adapt western standards.  相似文献   
10.
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号