全文获取类型
收费全文 | 208篇 |
免费 | 1篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 32篇 |
工业经济 | 15篇 |
计划管理 | 47篇 |
经济学 | 50篇 |
综合类 | 1篇 |
运输经济 | 2篇 |
旅游经济 | 1篇 |
贸易经济 | 36篇 |
农业经济 | 7篇 |
经济概况 | 18篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 3篇 |
2021年 | 2篇 |
2020年 | 7篇 |
2019年 | 3篇 |
2018年 | 11篇 |
2017年 | 5篇 |
2016年 | 5篇 |
2015年 | 4篇 |
2014年 | 13篇 |
2013年 | 23篇 |
2012年 | 16篇 |
2011年 | 9篇 |
2010年 | 21篇 |
2009年 | 7篇 |
2008年 | 7篇 |
2007年 | 9篇 |
2006年 | 9篇 |
2005年 | 7篇 |
2004年 | 2篇 |
2003年 | 4篇 |
2001年 | 2篇 |
2000年 | 4篇 |
1999年 | 5篇 |
1998年 | 2篇 |
1997年 | 1篇 |
1996年 | 6篇 |
1995年 | 4篇 |
1994年 | 4篇 |
1993年 | 4篇 |
1992年 | 1篇 |
1991年 | 4篇 |
1990年 | 1篇 |
1989年 | 1篇 |
1987年 | 1篇 |
1982年 | 1篇 |
1981年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有209条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
1.
Dag Einar Sommervoll 《Journal of Economics》2013,109(1):73-88
People have a tendency to procrastinate when faced with aversive tasks—but they also procrastinate in relation to beneficial matters whose rewards are instantaneous. If agents value present anticipations of future consumption, revision of consumption plans may be viewed as a benign form of self-deception. We consider a minimal generalization of the Samuelson discounted utility model to allow for utility linked to next period consumption. Agents are assumed to vary with respect to their sophistication. In this context, commitment and self-control are obstacles to the pursuit of increased utility. We also examine different environments that are likely to facilitate repeated revisions. 相似文献
2.
Morten Søberg 《Environmental and Resource Economics》2000,17(3):259-277
This paper reports a preliminary experimental test of international quota trading on a market characterized by several dominant traders. Uncertain quota demand and supply imply true market-clearing prices that in general differ from an expected competitive quota price. However, in the experiment the expected price level emerges as a focal point on which the bulk of quota trade contracts are keyed. Thus, incomplete price discovery occurs. 相似文献
3.
We discuss the relative merits of public and private ownership in an incomplete contract framework developed by Hart, Shleifer and Vishney (HSV). We add two new elements to their model. First, the government may offer cost‐sharing contracts when procuring the good. Second, the owner of a private firm may divert resources that increase their own profit/utility but increase total costs. The cost sharing contract allows the government to reduce the private firm's incentives to dump quality in order to save on costs. However, this also leads to resource diversion, which increases total costs. We derive the preferred mode of ownership when the government optimally chooses the power of the cost sharing scheme. We find that the presence of quality‐reducing cost reductions only favours government ownership if the scope for resource diversion is substantial. A discussion of when resource diversion is likely to be important is also provided. 相似文献
4.
Elicitation using multiple price list formats 总被引:2,自引:0,他引:2
Steffen Andersen Glenn W. Harrison Morten Igel Lau E. Elisabet Rutström 《Experimental Economics》2006,9(4):383-405
We examine the properties of a popular method for eliciting choices and values from experimental subjects, the multiple price
list format. The main advantage of this format is that it is relatively transparent to subjects and provides simple incentives
for truthful revelation. The main disadvantages are that it only elicits interval responses, and could be susceptible to framing
effects. We consider extensions to address and evaluate these concerns. We conclude that although there are framing effects,
they can be controlled for with a design that allows for them. We also find that the elicitation of risk attitudes is sensitive
to procedures, subject pools, and the format of the multiple price list table, but that the qualitative findings that participants
are generally risk averse is robust. The elicitation of discount rates appear less sensitive to details of the experimental
design.
Electronic Supplementary Material Supplementary material is available in the online version of this article at
.
JEL Classification C9, D81, D91
An erratum to this article is available at . 相似文献
5.
6.
Hilde C. Bjørnland Dag Henning Jacobsen 《The Scandinavian journal of economics》2013,115(4):1084-1106
We analyze the role of house prices and stock prices in the monetary‐policy transmission mechanism in the US, using a structural vector autoregressive model. If we allow the interest rate and asset prices to react simultaneously to news, we find different roles for house prices and stock prices in the monetary transmission mechanism. Following a contractionary monetary‐policy shock, stock prices fall immediately, while the response in house prices is more gradual. Regarding the systematic response in monetary policy, stock prices play a more important role than house prices. As a consequence, house prices contribute more than stock prices to fluctuations in gross domestic product and inflation. 相似文献
7.
Florian K. Diekert Dag Ø. Hjermann Eric Nævdal Nils Chr. Stenseth 《Resource and Energy Economics》2010,32(1):78-92
North-East Arctic cod is shared by Russia and Norway. Taking its multi-cohort structure into account, how would optimal management look like? How would non-cooperative exploitation limit the obtainable profits? To which extent could the strategic situation explain today’s over-harvesting? Simulation of a detailed bio-economic model reveals that the mesh size should be significantly increased, resulting not only in a doubling of economic gains, but also in a biologically healthier age-structure of the stock. The Nash equilibrium is close to the current regime. Even when effort is fixed to its optimal level, the non-cooperative choice of gear selectivity leads to a large dissipation of rents. 相似文献
8.
9.
10.
Alessandro Minichilli Jonas Gabrielsson Morten Huse 《Corporate Governance: An International Review》2007,15(4):609-622
Board evaluations can contribute to effective boards and improved corporate financial performance. The increasing interest in the practice of board evaluations, however, calls for a more systematic and careful approach than has been employed in the past. While most attention has primarily been focused on the content of board evaluations, this article outlines the features of various possible board evaluation systems. Based on state‐of‐the‐art research on boards and governance, we contend that a comprehensive board evaluation system needs to include decisions about: (a) the agent who evaluates the board; (b) the content, or what the evaluation should deal with; (c) the addressee and other stakeholders for whom the board is evaluated; and (d) how the board is evaluated. These key decisions should not be seen as independent of each other as they have consequences for the kind of system that will be adopted. Following this argument, we present four different board evaluation systems: (i) board‐to‐board, (ii) board‐to‐market, (iii) market‐to‐board and (iv) market‐to‐market. The key message we communicate in this article is that there must be a fit between the purpose and the system of board evaluations. There is no universal or “one best way” to evaluate boards of directors. Board evaluations will not meet their purpose unless there is a fit between the agents, the addressees, the content and the modalities of the evaluation. It is important to know who is doing what for whom and how. 相似文献