排序方式: 共有23条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
1.
Consistent with real option theory, the authors argue that the value of the Employment Guarantee Scheme (EGS) in rural India and its impact on workers' behavior does not depend so much on its income supplementation as on enlargement of opportunities in the uncertain local labor market. The choice between the EGS and other activities is modeled in a dynamic optimization framework, taking into account a fixed wage rate and certainty of employment under the EGS and a stochastic wage rate under other activities. Specifically, volatility of wages in the rural labor markets has important implications for switches into the EGS and for concomitant welfare effects. Under such conditions, the higher the EGS wage, the greater is its attractiveness to relatively skilled and affluent workers, and for those already in it to continue. These and related predictions of the model are validated by panel data estimation. 相似文献
2.
In this paper, the relationship is assessed between possessing information on, gaining access to and the efficacy of delivery of India's national rural employment guarantee scheme (NREGA) in three states. The results suggest that the link between information, access and the delivery of the scheme is not straightforward. Information can increase the propensity for the programme to be accessed by those who are not its primary target population, and can enhance efficacy of delivery to such beneficiaries. Lack of information, on the other hand, decreases the ability of citizens, particularly the acutely poor, to benefit from the scheme. 相似文献
3.
Raghav Gaiha & Katsushi Imai 《Oxford Development Studies》2013,41(2):261-281
This paper focuses on the vulnerability of rural households to poverty when a negative crop shock occurs. The analysis is based on the ICRISAT panel survey of households in a semi‐arid region in south India during 1975–84. Using a dynamic panel data model that takes into account effects of crop shocks, an assessment of vulnerability of different groups of households is carried out. What is somewhat surprising is that even sections of relatively affluent households are highly vulnerable to long spells of poverty when severe crop shocks occur. As such crop shocks are frequent in a harsh production environment, there must be a shift of emphasis in anti‐poverty measures from meeting income shortfalls among the poor to enabling the vulnerable to protect themselves better against these shocks. 相似文献
4.
5.
Drawing upon the Vietnam Household Living Standards Survey (VHLSS) data that cover the whole of Vietnam in 2002 and 2004, ex ante measures of vulnerability are constructed. These are then compared with static indicators of poverty (i.e. the headcount ratio in a particular year). Detailed analyses of the panel data show that (i) in general, vulnerability in 2002 translates into poverty in 2004; (ii) vulnerability of the poor tends to perpetuate their poverty and (iii) sections of the nonpoor but vulnerable slip into poverty. Durable reduction in poverty is conditional on (i) accurate identification of the vulnerable, (ii) their sources of vulnerability and (iii) design of social safety nets that would enable the vulnerable to reduce risks and cope better with rapid integration of markets with the larger global economy. 相似文献
6.
Nidhi Kaicker;Aashi Gupta;Raghav Gaiha; 《Review of Development Economics》2024,28(2):527-543
Using three-stage least squares, the present study examines how the household expenditure on socialising activities, including eating out, entertainment and religious and social obligations changed during the COVID-19 pandemic in India. Our results suggest a negative impact of COVID-19 cases on the socialising expenditure shares of the households. Further, a higher spending on food is associated with a lower spending on socialising. We find that during the crisis, the increased food expenditures entails lower discretionary expenditures. Or, in other words, they are substitutes. A quadratic socialising expenditures curve confirms the expenditure variability and the wide-ranging responses of households belonging to different income groups to the COVID-19 induced economic shocks. The rising prices of food and other necessities required the households to spend larger shares of their incomes on necessary goods, and curtail the consumption of leisure goods. The role of maintaining a healthy work-life balance, active social network as well as leisure activities to be content in life is well documented. Hence a reduced expenditure on socialising due to the pandemic, may throw light on some larger and significant concerns such as the deteriorating mental health of individuals and greater stress and frustration. 相似文献
7.
Raghav Gaiha 《Journal of development economics》1980,7(2):273-282
Scepticism is often expressed about plan models for their reliance on input-output relationships based on not-very-recent data. An attempt is made in this paper to demonstrate, with Indian data, that temporal changes in input-output relationships in general are likely to be small. In a few crucial cases, however, the changes may be more than nominal and adjustments for intra-sectoral product mix and technological changes would be necessary for minimising the errors in intermediate demand projections. While the applicability of these findings to economies with a slow rate of growth seems plausible, the same cannot be said for other developing economies experiencing a much faster rate of growth. 相似文献
8.
Raghbendra Jha Raghav Gaiha Anurag Sharma 《International Review of Applied Economics》2009,23(4):503-519
In this paper we compute nutrient‐income elasticities for two macronutrients (calories and protein) and five micronutrients (calcium, thiamine, riboflavin, carotene and iron) using an all‐India sample of rural households for 1994. We show that in each case the respective elasticities are positive and significant. This lends support to our hypothesis that an increase in income would increase nutrient intake by varying amounts, contrary to some assertions. We then compute differences in the elasticity of substitution for non‐poor and poor across commodity groups and show that these differences, while significant, are small. This further corroborates our conclusion that increases in income of the poor would lead to greater increases in their nutrient intake as compared to the non‐poor, although the magnitudes will be small. 相似文献
9.
Raghav Gaiha 《Economics of Planning》2000,33(3):203-219
Contrary to a widely held view, the targeting of the Employment Guarantee Scheme in the Indian state of Maharashtra was unsatisfactory
and worsened over the period 1979–89. Among the participants, from a large group the non-poor became the majority. Some of
them were in fact (moderately) affluent. The share of female participants – especially of poor female participants – also
diminished. As a result, the overall share of poor in EGS earnings fell sharply. Although a greater targeting accuracy does
not necessarily imply a greater poverty impact for a given outlay, some improvements in the design and implementation of this
scheme are likely to enhance both.
This revised version was published online in July 2006 with corrections to the Cover Date. 相似文献
10.
Summary deal with an organization havingm individual agents (the agents) and one central agent or agency (the coordinator), and the problem of allocating a fixed supply ofn commodities among the agents. The coordinator wishes to distribute the commodities in such a way as to maximize an objective function whose arguments are functions known (implicitly) to the individual agents, but not to the coordinator. The more information the coordinator obtains about the individual agents' functions, the better the allocation decision he or she can make; however, gaining such information is costly, so that the coordinator must balance the potential gain against the cost of acquiring additional information. We find a satisficing solution to this problem which is computable and which terminates in a finite number of steps.We would like to thank Leo Hurwicz, Ken Matheny, Shailendra Mehta, Bill Novshek, Roy Radner, Stan Reiter, Vernon Smith, Mark Walker, and, especially, John Ledyard and Tom Marschak, for helpful comments and suggestions. We must, of course, however reluctantly, accept responsibility for any remaining defects. 相似文献