首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   1016篇
  免费   93篇
  国内免费   12篇
财政金融   208篇
工业经济   53篇
计划管理   167篇
经济学   210篇
综合类   175篇
运输经济   4篇
旅游经济   14篇
贸易经济   118篇
农业经济   51篇
经济概况   121篇
  2024年   7篇
  2023年   29篇
  2022年   16篇
  2021年   19篇
  2020年   36篇
  2019年   37篇
  2018年   38篇
  2017年   33篇
  2016年   32篇
  2015年   32篇
  2014年   54篇
  2013年   96篇
  2012年   75篇
  2011年   73篇
  2010年   66篇
  2009年   52篇
  2008年   73篇
  2007年   81篇
  2006年   74篇
  2005年   56篇
  2004年   29篇
  2003年   27篇
  2002年   17篇
  2001年   14篇
  2000年   12篇
  1999年   15篇
  1998年   6篇
  1997年   4篇
  1996年   4篇
  1995年   2篇
  1994年   3篇
  1993年   1篇
  1992年   2篇
  1991年   1篇
  1990年   1篇
  1989年   1篇
  1986年   2篇
  1983年   1篇
排序方式: 共有1121条查询结果,搜索用时 250 毫秒
1.
One feature common to many post‐socialist transition economies is a relatively compressed wage structure in the state‐owned sector. We conjecture that this compressed wage structure creates weak incentives for work effort and worker skill acquisition and thus presents adverse consequences for the entire transition economy if a substantial portion of the labour force works in the state sector. We explore firm wage incentives and worker training, as well as other labour practices and outcomes, in a transition setting with matched firm and worker data collected in one of the largest provinces of Vietnam – Ho Chi Minh City. The Vietnamese state sector exhibits a compressed wage distribution in relation to privately owned firms with foreign ownership. State wage practices stress tenure over worker productivity and their wage policies result in flatter wage–experience profiles and lower returns to education. The state work force is in greater need of formal training, a need that is in part met through direct government financing. In spite of the opportunities for government financed training and at least partly due to inefficient worker incentives, state firms, by certain measures, exhibit lower levels of labour productivity. The private sector comparison group to state firms for all of these findings is foreign owned firms. The internal labour practices of foreign firms are more consistent with a view of profit‐maximizing firms operating with no political constraints. This is not the case for Vietnamese de novo private firms that exhibit much more idiosyncratic behaviour and whose labour practices are often indistinguishable from state firms. The exact reasons for this remain a topic of on‐going research yet we conjecture that various private sector constraints, including limited access to formal capital, play an important role.  相似文献   
2.
深化乡镇综合改革难点研究   总被引:3,自引:1,他引:2  
乡镇机构人员膨胀是当前农民负担过重的主要原因之一。而20多年来乡镇机构减而复胀且日益严重,成为改革的难点。乡镇职能错位、各类机构关系不顺、社会改革不配套,还有行政机构中客观存在的“帕金森定律”,是乡镇机构改革难点形成的深层原因。深化乡镇综合改革的远期目标是实现乡镇自治,而近期目标则是以转变职能为核心,调整政府管理体制;实现乡镇机构的功能整合;同时可以实行政府职能“外包”;还要加强机构编制的法治管理。  相似文献   
3.
We provide evidence on the impact of tax incentives and financial constraints on corporate R&D expenditure decisions. We contribute to extant research by comparing R&D expenditures in the United States and Canada, thereby exploiting the differences in the two countries' R&D tax credit mechanisms and generally accepted accounting principles. The two tax incentive mechanism designs are consistent with differing views of the degree of financial constraints faced by firms in these economies. Our sample also allows us to explore the effects of capitalizing R&D on Canadian firms. Employing a matched design, we document relations between tax credit incentives and R&D spending consistent with both Canadian and U.S. public companies responding as though they are not financially constrained. We estimate that the Canadian credit system induces, on average, $1.30 of additional R&D spending per dollar of taxes forgone while the U.S. system induces, on average, $2.96 of additional spending. We also find that firms that capitalize R&D costs in Canada spend, on average, 18 percent more on R&D. Collectively, this evidence is important to the ongoing debates in both countries concerning the appropriate design of incentives for R&D and is consistent with the assumptions found in the U.S. tax credit system, but not those found in the Canadian system.  相似文献   
4.
5.
家族集团中,在企业家通过本期产出水平来确定子公司经理人所应上缴的产出分配收益的情况下,经理人会通过调整自己的努力水平,间接控制自己在下期的上缴额度,从而导致激励效率损失.但是,如果企业家能收取固定的产出分配收益,并确定高额违约金,就能够有效地规避子公司经理人代理问题.  相似文献   
6.
基于知识型组织员工人力资源的独有特征,提出一种新的人性假设——“价值人”假设,即知识型组织中员工是工具价值与自我价值二维存在的统一体。在“价值人”假设条件下,知识型组织员工管理模式应从传统的“命令-控制”型向“引导-激励”型转变,运用激励的制度安排来激发员工的工作热情。  相似文献   
7.
论地质工作中人才激励机制的构建   总被引:2,自引:1,他引:1  
《国务院关于加强地质工作的决定》在对地质工作人才现状进行科学判断的基础上,指出要加快地质人才开发、发挥地质工作者的积极性和创造性,为如何构建地质工作人才激励机制指明了方向。文章分析了目前地勘单位人才资源现状及地质专业人才匮乏的原因;提出了建立地勘单位的人才引进机制、内部分配机制、培训机制、社会的人才培养机制等观点。  相似文献   
8.
This paper examines a scheme of economic incentives for environmental protection, in which spatially differentiated pollution taxes are in use in compensating the pollution abatement costs. A simple mathematical model is described which determines an incentive system that encourages polluters to reduce the discharges to an acceptable level of ambient quality standards in a cost-effective manner. It is shown that the vector of pollution charges has to be proportional to the marginal abatement cost vector, but is smaller than the latter in magnitude. It is demonstrated that a necessary incentive effect may be achieved even if the total pollution charge is much lower (about three times) than the total abatement costs. It is also estimated how this charge incentive system reconciles conflicting criteria of cost-effectiveness and of equity. These conclusions are verified by numerical experiments with real data.  相似文献   
9.
“通过制定、发布和实施标准,达到统一”是标准化的实质,“获得最佳秩序和社会效益”则是标准化的目的。制定行业标准是为了规范行业内企业行为。并方便社会公众对业内行为规范的识别和监督。  相似文献   
10.
农村创新分为原始要素主导、初级要素主导、中级要素主导和高级要素主导四个阶段,包括需求创新、要素创新、产业创新、环境创新、组织创新、体制创新和文化创新.长江上游地区农村创新总体上处于初级要素主导阶段,并存在七大障碍.因此,长江上游地区农村创新的基本模式是政府主导型的,必须全面建立初步的农村创新体系;构筑利于中级水平创新的钻石结构,推进重点农村区域的创新;打牢农村小康的环境基础和村民素质基础,突破难点区域的农村创新.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号