首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   633篇
  免费   19篇
财政金融   126篇
工业经济   28篇
计划管理   88篇
经济学   184篇
综合类   4篇
运输经济   5篇
旅游经济   3篇
贸易经济   100篇
农业经济   57篇
经济概况   47篇
邮电经济   10篇
  2022年   2篇
  2021年   4篇
  2020年   14篇
  2019年   11篇
  2018年   13篇
  2017年   14篇
  2016年   24篇
  2015年   13篇
  2014年   22篇
  2013年   71篇
  2012年   22篇
  2011年   32篇
  2010年   36篇
  2009年   23篇
  2008年   24篇
  2007年   27篇
  2006年   21篇
  2005年   23篇
  2004年   18篇
  2003年   23篇
  2002年   18篇
  2001年   17篇
  2000年   19篇
  1999年   11篇
  1998年   7篇
  1997年   11篇
  1996年   11篇
  1995年   7篇
  1994年   7篇
  1993年   8篇
  1992年   5篇
  1991年   4篇
  1990年   4篇
  1989年   4篇
  1988年   4篇
  1987年   3篇
  1986年   3篇
  1985年   5篇
  1984年   6篇
  1983年   5篇
  1982年   10篇
  1981年   7篇
  1980年   6篇
  1979年   7篇
  1978年   3篇
  1977年   5篇
  1976年   4篇
  1975年   2篇
  1970年   4篇
  1969年   2篇
排序方式: 共有652条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
41.
42.
Total Factor Productivity, the East Asian Miracle, and the World Production Frontier. — The post WWII growth of the East Asian Tiger states has stimulated the discussion about its determinants. Young and Krugman hold that high capital accumulation rather than gains in efficiency or technological progress has spurred growth. Nelson and Pack, however, have recently criticized the methods of measuring technological progress. Applying the nonparametric approach to frontier production function determination and the Malmquist index of total factor productivity change, the authors take up this criticism. They calculate productivity indicators for a sample of 18 American, Asian, and European countries. For the Tiger states, their results confirm that capital accumulation was the main source of growth in 1960-1973, whereas they find evidence for an increasing importance of efficiency improvements for the growth in 1973-1990.  相似文献   
43.
Portfolio credit risk models as well as models for operational risk can often be treated analogously to the collective risk model coming from insurance. Applying the classical Panjer recursion in the collective risk model can lead to numerical instabilities, for instance if the claim number distribution is extended negative binomial or extended logarithmic. We present a generalization of Panjer’s recursion that leads to numerically stable algorithms. The algorithm can be applied to the collective risk model, where the claim number follows, for example, a Poisson distribution mixed over a generalized tempered stable distribution with exponent in (0,1). De Pril’s recursion can be generalized in the same vein. We also present an analogue of our method for the collective model with a severity distribution having mixed support.  相似文献   
44.
45.
46.
Uwe Wilkesmann 《Publizistik》2000,45(4):476-495
This article mainly concentrates on two questions: 1. What functions does an internal corporate communication perform in a learning organization, and in relation to knowledge management? 2. Under which conditions or circumstances can internal corporate communication fulfill these functions? In the concepts of organizational learning and knowledge management, internal communication gains an important productive function in generating, processing and saving knowledge. Instruments and tools such as face-to-face communication, internal magazines, information boards and the use of an intranet are discussed. As far as the generation, production and saving of knowledge are concerned, the instrument of face-to-face communication and the intranet are gaining special importance. In order to cope with these functional challenges, the internal corporate communication has to institutionalize selective incentives and motivating factors. For generating and saving knowledge, the actors’ reception of these media of communication seems of great importance also: Only a unified «community of practice» is able to transform information into knowledge.  相似文献   
47.
48.
49.
This paper explores farmers’ willingness to adopt genetically modified (GM) oilseed rape prior to its commercial release and estimates the ‘demand’ for the new technology. The analysis is based upon choice experiments with 202 German arable farmers. A multinomial probit estimation reveals that GM attributes such as gross margin, expected liability from cross pollination, or flexibility in returning to conventional oilseed rape significantly affect the likelihood of adoption. Neighbouring farmers’ attitudes towards GM cropping and a number of farmer and farm characteristics were also found to be significant determinants of prospective adoption. Demand simulations suggest that adoption rates are very sensitive to the profit difference between GM and non‐GM rape varieties. A monopolistic seed price would substantially reduce demand for the new technology. A monopolistic seed supplier would reap between 45% and 80% of the GM rent, and the deadweight loss of the monopoly would range between 15% and 30% of that rent. The remaining rent for farmers may be too small to outweigh possible producer price discounts resulting from the costs of segregating GM and non‐GM oilseed rape along the supply chain.  相似文献   
50.
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号