首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   1100篇
  免费   93篇
  国内免费   10篇
财政金融   179篇
工业经济   79篇
计划管理   243篇
经济学   241篇
综合类   96篇
运输经济   11篇
旅游经济   23篇
贸易经济   164篇
农业经济   69篇
经济概况   98篇
  2024年   3篇
  2023年   32篇
  2022年   18篇
  2021年   33篇
  2020年   59篇
  2019年   46篇
  2018年   43篇
  2017年   31篇
  2016年   62篇
  2015年   44篇
  2014年   71篇
  2013年   111篇
  2012年   72篇
  2011年   83篇
  2010年   63篇
  2009年   56篇
  2008年   59篇
  2007年   54篇
  2006年   50篇
  2005年   47篇
  2004年   30篇
  2003年   24篇
  2002年   18篇
  2001年   22篇
  2000年   13篇
  1999年   13篇
  1998年   12篇
  1997年   6篇
  1996年   5篇
  1995年   7篇
  1994年   1篇
  1993年   3篇
  1992年   2篇
  1991年   1篇
  1990年   4篇
  1989年   2篇
  1986年   1篇
  1983年   1篇
  1982年   1篇
排序方式: 共有1203条查询结果,搜索用时 359 毫秒
71.
We propose a simple dynamical model for the formation of production networks among monopolistically competitive firms. The model subsumes the standard general equilibrium approach à la Arrow–Debreu but displays a wide set of potential dynamic behaviors. It robustly reproduces key stylized facts of firms׳ demographics. Our main result is that competition between intermediate good producers generically leads to the emergence of scale-free production networks.  相似文献   
72.
本文从住宅套型的声环境、光环境、热舒适环境和通风环境四大方面入手,对影响住宅套型性能质量之物理性能质量进行探讨。  相似文献   
73.
This paper investigates the extent of nonstationarity of beta across the firm size and the beta magnitude by suggesting the sequential parameter stationarity model and estimating change-points of betas. The high-beta firm has shorter stationary interval, which means that its beta changes more frequently than do the low-beta firm's. The firm size, however, does not have a monotonic relation with the length of stationary interval. The small and large firms have relatively shorter stationary interval than do the mid-sized firms. The average length of stationary interval is estimated about five years (exactly 54.19 months). This fact could support the currently widely-used arbitrary 5-year assumption of beta stationarity. The fluctuation of the large firm's beta is more severe than the small firm's, and the high- and low-beta firms have the relatively greater fluctuating betas than do the mid-beta firms. The frequency of detected change-points is found to be positively related to market returns. When the market return is high, the systematic risk changes more frequently, and vice versa.  相似文献   
74.

This paper examines three important issues related to the relationship between stock returns and volatility. First, are Duffee's (1995) findings of the relationship between individual stock returns and volatility valid at the portfolio level? Second, is there a seasonality of the market return volatility? Lastly, do size portfolio returns react symmetrically to the market volatility during business cycles? We find that the market volatility exhibits strong autocorrelation and small size portfolio returns exhibit seasonality. However, this phenomenon is not present in large size portfolios. For the entire sample period of 1962–1995, the highest average monthly volatility occurred in October, followed by November, and then January. Examining the two sub-sample periods, we find that the average market volatility increases by 15.4% in the second sample period of 1980–1995 compared to the first sample period of 1962–1979. During the contraction period, the average market volatility is 60.9% higher than that during the expansion period. Using a binary regression model, we find that size portfolio returns react asymmetrically with the market volatility during business cycles. This paper documents a strongly negative contemporaneous relationship between the size portfolio returns and the market volatility that is consistent with the previous findings at the aggregate level, but is inconsistent with the findings at the individual firm level. In contrast with the previous findings, however, we find an ambiguous relationship between the percentage change in the market volatility and the contemporaneous stock portfolio returns. This ambiguity is attributed to strongly negative contemporaneous and one-month ahead relationships between the market volatility and portfolio returns.

  相似文献   
75.
本文系统研究了用分组垫片法解装配尺寸链时的计算方法。提出了改进和完善用分组垫片法解装配尺寸链的四个问题:组成环经济公差的标准化;理论计算垫片分组数的取整;每组垫片的分配数量和装配尺寸链的概率计算法。并给出了相应的分析和计算方法,使其理论能够更准确、更方便地运用于实际设计过程中。  相似文献   
76.
Low birth rates, longevity, family disintegration, and other factors have reduced the size of the average household. At the same time household size is shrinking, new housing offers twice the floor space per occupant of old housing. Small households are inefficient users of space, utilities, furniture, and equipment. As these factors converge, the result is over consumption of durables and vast stockpiles of possessions just awaiting disposal when the baby boom generation passes on. The rightful heirs to these possessions are themselves accumulators, and will most likely have little use for what is left to them. What does the future hold for consumption, savings, and demand for housing? Booming flea markets, bigger homes as warehouses, a decline in consumption, or an epidemic of display and collection? Public policies have limited leverage on private behavior.  相似文献   
77.
通过对美国共同基金关于基金规模的数学模型分析,我们发现基金规模与基金经理人能力和流动性赎回密不可分。从美国的有关模型分析与优秀经验来谈我国为确定基金规模所采取的措施:首先讨论了保证基金管理人发挥其能力的一些政策性建议,其次讨论了减少流动性赎回所采取的措施。  相似文献   
78.
This paper starts from the stylized fact that firm size and exporting tends to be positively related. Using large sets of establishment panel data for three different industries from official statistics, evidence is presented that the familiar picture of an export/sales ratio that increases (at a decreasing rate) with firm size vanishes if unobserved firm heterogeneity is controlled for in a fixed-effects fractional logit regression model. This finding is well in line with the fact that many small firms are “hidden export champions.” JEL no. F10, D21, L60  相似文献   
79.
基于12家商业银行1997~2005年间的数据,对商业银行信息技术资本的边际生产率和最优投入规模的实证研究结果表明,我国商业银行信息技术资本的边际生产率是正的,且其大小受银行规模和时间的影响;四大商业银行信息技术资本的边际生产率小于中小规模商业银行;银行整体的信息技术资本边际生产率随时间呈现不断增长的趋势;四大商业银行信息技术投资已经超过了最优规模,而中小商业银行尚未达到最优规模。四大商业银行应该着重提高信息技术资本的利用率,完善互补机制,而中小商业银行应进一步加大信息技术的投资量。研究结果证明,当前“信息技术生产率悖论”在我国商业银行中并不成立。  相似文献   
80.
杨晓敏 《金融论坛》2007,12(5):41-47
通过在金融资产结构与经济增长模型中引入能够综合反映制度变迁的制度变量,证明国家制度变迁对一国金融资产结构与经济增长会起到促进或制约的作用.当制度供给与金融资产结构和经济增长对制度的需求达到均衡时,国家制度安排会优化金融资产结构、促进经济增长,否则便会出现规模与效率的"反比"现象,从而回答了我国金融资产规模与效率之间为什么出现悖论的问题.我国应积极发展非银行金融机构,实现金融体系多元化,对内开放,满足我国经济对多层次、多样化金融的需求,完善金融市场准入制度,优化市场参与主体结构,促进股票市场和银行协调发展.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号