首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   291篇
  免费   5篇
财政金融   109篇
工业经济   7篇
计划管理   35篇
经济学   45篇
综合类   36篇
旅游经济   3篇
贸易经济   22篇
农业经济   5篇
经济概况   34篇
  2023年   2篇
  2022年   1篇
  2021年   3篇
  2020年   7篇
  2019年   4篇
  2018年   6篇
  2017年   9篇
  2016年   12篇
  2015年   5篇
  2014年   23篇
  2013年   50篇
  2012年   17篇
  2011年   21篇
  2010年   11篇
  2009年   13篇
  2008年   29篇
  2007年   25篇
  2006年   19篇
  2005年   15篇
  2004年   5篇
  2003年   10篇
  2002年   3篇
  2001年   1篇
  2000年   4篇
  1983年   1篇
排序方式: 共有296条查询结果,搜索用时 46 毫秒
1.
Has the Chinese economy approached the ‘Lewisian turning point’ that marks the ending of the initial phase of industrial transformation fuelled by surplus labour? In this paper we undertake an interpretative survey of the literature on this issue, in the context of China's labour market conditions prior to the reforms and structural change of the past three decades. The available evidence is mixed, and our assessment makes a strong case for probing institutional constraints to labour mobility from an economy‐wide perspective, going beyond the confines of the rural economy.  相似文献   
2.
缔约过失责任系缔约阶段因缔约人过失地违反依诚实信用原则而依法应承担的先合同义务而产生的民事责任。我国《合同法》确立了此项制度 ,但有其不完善之处 ,有待于立法上的完善。  相似文献   
3.
厂用电的连续可靠是发电机组安全运行的基本条件,如何在厂用电的事故切换中做到可靠、精确与快速是近几年人们关注的问题,本装置提供了一种快速可靠的切换方法。  相似文献   
4.
Why did England industrialize first? And why was Europe ahead of the rest of the world? Unified growth theory in the tradition of Galor and Weil (2000, American Economic Review, 89, 806–828) and Galor and Moav (2002, Quartely Journal of Economics, 177(4), 1133–1191) captures the key features of the transition from stagnation to growth over time. Yet we know remarkably little about why industrialization occurred much earlier in some parts of the world than in others. To answer this question, we present a probabilistic two-sector model where the initial escape from Malthusian constraints depends on the demographic regime, capital deepening and the use of more differentiated capital equipment. Weather-induced shocks to agricultural productivity cause changes in prices and quantities, and affect wages. In a standard model with capital externalities, these fluctuations interact with the demographic regime and affect the speed of growth. Our model is calibrated to match the main characteristics of the English economy in 1700 and the observed transition until 1850. We capture one of the key features of the British Industrial Revolution emphasized by economic historians — slow growth of output and productivity. Fertility limitation is responsible for higher per capita incomes, and these in turn increase industrialization probabilities. The paper also explores the availability of nutrition for poorer segments of society. We examine the influence of redistributive institutions such as the Old Poor Law, and find they were not decisive in fostering industrialization. Simulations using parameter values for other countries show that Britain’s early escape was only partly due to chance. France could have moved out of agriculture and into manufacturing faster than Britain, but the probability was less than 25%. Contrary to recent claims in the literature, 18th century China had only a minimal chance to escape from Malthusian constraints.  相似文献   
5.
投资与通货膨胀-紧缩的联系:来自中国的经验证据   总被引:9,自引:0,他引:9  
基于Toda-Yamamoto长期因果检验程序和广义脉冲反应技术,本文首先研究了全社会实际固定资产投资与零售价格水平变动之间的长期因果及其冲击-动态反应关系,然后进一步考察了货币供给量M1和贸易依存度在促成上述关系中所扮演的角色.其研究结论为:(1)货币供给量M1是唯一的外生变量,其增长不是价格水平变动的直接因,而是通过全社会实际固定资产投资间接地成为价格水平变动的因;(2)贸易依存度和全社会实际固定资产投资之间存在双向因果联系,前者只能通过后者间接地成为价格水平变动的因;(3)中国对外开放既消化又强化了中国生产能力过剩,但消化胜于强化;(4)投资一个单位正向冲击在开始的2-4年左右导致相对温和的通货膨胀,但后五年左右将导致相对严重的通货紧缩.  相似文献   
6.
本文从分析盈余管理的概念出发,指出上市公司盈余管理的实质是企业管理当局追求利益最大化的一种博弈行为。基于这样的认识,结合博弈论的相关原理,笔者从会计信息不对称、会计政策的制订和选择两方面分析了盈余管理行为产生的原因,并进一步分析了上市公司进行盈余管理的动机,最后提出了相应的建议和对策。  相似文献   
7.
由于农村剩余劳动力数量庞大而素质较低,再加上观念认识不到位,组织管理工作滞后,就业环境不完善等,导致农村剩余劳动力转移困难,影响农民增加收入和农村小康社会建设。因此,必须采取多种措施,广辟就业渠道,优化就业环境,大力发展劳务中介组织,加强管理和协调,以使农村剩余劳动力有效有序地转移。  相似文献   
8.
9.
We consider an insurance company whose surplus is represented by the classical Cramer-Lundberg process. The company can invest its surplus in a risk-free asset and in a risky asset, governed by the Black-Scholes equation. There is a constraint that the insurance company can only invest in the risky asset at a limited leveraging level; more precisely, when purchasing, the ratio of the investment amount in the risky asset to the surplus level is no more than a; and when short-selling, the proportion of the proceeds from the short-selling to the surplus level is no more than b. The objective is to find an optimal investment policy that minimizes the probability of ruin. The minimal ruin probability as a function of the initial surplus is characterized by a classical solution to the corresponding Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) equation. We study the optimal control policy and its properties. The interrelation between the parameters of the model plays a crucial role in the qualitative behavior of the optimal policy. For example, for some ratios between a and b, quite unusual and at first ostensibly counterintuitive policies may appear, like short-selling a stock with a higher rate of return to earn lower interest, or borrowing at a higher rate to invest in a stock with lower rate of return. This is in sharp contrast with the unrestricted case, first studied in Hipp and Plum, or with the case of no short-selling and no borrowing studied in Azcue and Muler.  相似文献   
10.
The issue of surplus distribution has hardly been analyzed in the context of the social economy. This paper highlights the main drivers of distribution between various stakeholders of microfinance institutions (MFIs), which are an example of social enterprises. We focus on three major variables: size, governance structure and subsidies. Our results show that the size of the institution is the main indicator of the surplus that the organization keeps as a self-financial margin. Moreover, MFIs with a cooperative ownership structure allocate a larger part of their surplus to their employees, whereas non-profit organizations and shareholder-firm MFIs do not allocate their surplus in a significantly different way among their main stakeholders. Finally, we do not find any clear-cut effect of subsidies on the surplus allocation process.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号