首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   675篇
  免费   19篇
  国内免费   2篇
财政金融   104篇
工业经济   13篇
计划管理   54篇
经济学   185篇
综合类   68篇
运输经济   3篇
旅游经济   1篇
贸易经济   130篇
农业经济   22篇
经济概况   116篇
  2024年   2篇
  2023年   4篇
  2022年   8篇
  2021年   14篇
  2020年   21篇
  2019年   25篇
  2018年   16篇
  2017年   20篇
  2016年   25篇
  2015年   28篇
  2014年   55篇
  2013年   114篇
  2012年   25篇
  2011年   33篇
  2010年   25篇
  2009年   36篇
  2008年   48篇
  2007年   55篇
  2006年   38篇
  2005年   20篇
  2004年   20篇
  2003年   27篇
  2002年   7篇
  2001年   3篇
  2000年   4篇
  1999年   3篇
  1998年   3篇
  1997年   3篇
  1996年   3篇
  1995年   4篇
  1994年   1篇
  1992年   2篇
  1990年   2篇
  1989年   1篇
  1981年   1篇
排序方式: 共有696条查询结果,搜索用时 31 毫秒
1.
This paper investigates the heterogeneous income distribution effects of trade liberalization using Korean survey data from years of 2000–2015. Following the Stolper-Samuelson theorem most of previous research studying the effects of trade liberalization on wage differences focus on workers’ characteristics (e.g., skilled or unskilled) while heterogeneity within the same worker group has not been yet substantially investigated. To fill this gap, this paper provides empirical evidence of wage inequality across firms within the same group of workers caused by trade liberalization, potentially implied in the new-new trade models with firm heterogeneity. Employing a difference-in-differences (DID) specification, we find that the wages of unskilled workers in Korea have increased since its FTAs with more advanced countries, such as members of EU and the US, came into effect, while the effects on the wages of skilled workers are negative but not statistically significant. We also show that wage effects are heterogeneous across firms within unskilled and skilled worker groups, while the positive effects are statistically significant and largest for unskilled workers in medium-large sized firms. These findings are in line with both traditional and new-new trade models.  相似文献   
2.
This paper examines the phenomenon of the “Solow paradox” in China using the Annual Survey of Industrial Production database and the China Customs Records dataset from 1998 to 2007. We find that China likely fell into the Solow paradox in the period 1998–2002, but the total factor productivity of information and communication technology (ICT) enterprises has achieved rapid growth since 2003. Accession to the World Trade Organization is the key reason for China to overcome the Solow paradox, that is, input tariff reduction significantly promoted the productivity of ICT firms. A series of validity and robustness checks confirmed the results. Mechanism analysis shows that input liberalization promotes the productivity of ICT firms through optimizing factor structure, importing more and high-quality inputs, and increasing research and development investment. The conclusions provide strong empirical evidence for developing countries to overcome the Solow paradox through trade liberalization.  相似文献   
3.
This paper studies the lobbying against trade liberalization by both a firm and a union in the same industry. We find that the relationship between their political activities depends on the effect of political activity by one on the marginal effectiveness of political activity by the other. We also show that, when they are strongly risk-averse and their political activities are strategic complements, trade liberalization is likely to be successful if business is brisk, the foreign firm's production cost is high or the number of union members is small. However, when they are not strongly risk-averse, these results hold reversely.  相似文献   
4.
In January 1992, Kazakhstan initiated a reform programme to move towards market-determined prices. The price liberalization process was characterized by large relative price shifts and an increase in the overall price level towards those observed in market economies. The paper shows how the piecemeal manner in which prices were liberalized resulted in strong relative price variability over a prolonged period of time, against a background of high inflation. Convergence towards international relative and absolute price levels has progressed but is not complete, with prices for energy and services in particular still below market economy levels.  相似文献   
5.
资本账户开放是印度一揽子经济改革开放的重要组成部分,印度政府对资本账户开放采取了灵活而实用的态度.从直接投资、证券投资、商业性外部借款和非居民印度人计划4个方面介绍了20世纪90年代以来印度资本账户开放的主要内容,分析了银行改革、汇率制度与资本账户开放的关联性.印度和中国的资本账户开放进程拥有许多相似之处,也存在值得中国借鉴的经验和启示.  相似文献   
6.
1994年,亚太经济合作组织(以下简称APEC)确立了发达国家于2010年,发展中国家于2020年实现贸易和投资自由化的目标。贸易自由化目标的实现必将对亚太,乃至整个世界产生重要影响。利用可计算一般均衡模型(CGE)对APEC贸易自由化效果进行了模拟分析,结论是几乎所有APEC成员都能从中获益。根据模拟结果,中国作为其中一员,成为从贸易自由化的实现中获益较多的国家。  相似文献   
7.
Costly pollution abatement, competitiveness and plant location decisions   总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1  
The NAFTA debate included assertions that were used as arguments against trade and investment liberalization. (1) Trade liberalization increases production sensitivity to environmental restrictions (‘environmental dumping’?). (2) Investment liberalization, leading to multinational firms, similarly increases the production and welfare response to costly environmental restrictions. I find that: (1) Trade liberalization increases production sensitivity to costly environmental restrictions, but arguments against liberal trade on welfare grounds do not follow. (2) Multinationals do not increase the production-reallocation effect caused by environmental restrictions or regulations. In addition, I find a great difference between restrictions that fall on fixed costs and restrictions that fall on marginal costs.  相似文献   
8.
We provide an overview and introduction to the emerging field of trade and renewable resources, and discuss the potential impact of trade liberalization on welfare and resource conservation. A key factor determining the effect of trade reform is the institutional context or property rights regime, and our survey is organized such that it loosely follows the development of new insights with respect to institutions in this literature. This implies a transition from the benevolent planners model to the polar opposite benchmark of open access in the 1990s. Currently the pendulum is swinging back towards management and regulation, but institutions are treated as endogenous. We discuss and compare various key models in some detail and search for common ground between protagonists and antagonists of free trade. Paper based on Keynote address by Erwin Bulte, 12th Annual Conference of the European Association of Environmental and Resource Economists, Bilbao (Spain), June 28–30, 2003.  相似文献   
9.
李巍 《财经研究》2007,33(11):41-52
文章建立一个由金融发展程度、资本账户开放与金融不稳定指标组成的向量自回归(VAR)模型,利用中国1982~2005年的年度数据对这些变量的长期协整关系和短期的调整动力学进行相关的时间序列分析。模型的估计结果显示,对于中国来说,金融发展程度、资本账户开放和金融不稳定之间存在着长期的协整关系,但三者之间的影响程度和方向各不相同。所有结果均显示,无论从短期和长期看,金融发展程度对一国的金融稳定具有显著影响,对资本账户开放的进程也具有重要的影响。  相似文献   
10.
文章探讨了中国贸易自由化进程对犯罪活动的影响及其发生作用的机制。研究基于中国产品层面的关税数据,构建差异性的地区贸易保护指标,衡量各地区贸易自由化程度,进而利用2000-2011年省级面板数据,运用固定效应模型与工具变量法实证检验贸易自由化与犯罪率之间的关系及潜在人口流动的影响机制。结果表明:中国加入WTO后,贸易自由化显著推升了犯罪率水平,且贸易自由化程度越深入的省份,犯罪率提升程度越高,地区效应显著;贸易自由化主要通过增加外来人口流入等渠道推升了犯罪活动。因而,中国在进一步对外开放过程中,要注重处理好贸易自由化带来的负面效应和由此产生的额外社会成本,更加注重流动人口权益的保障,消除劳动力市场扭曲,最小化贸易自由化可能带来的不利影响。  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号