首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   204篇
  免费   4篇
财政金融   41篇
工业经济   5篇
计划管理   25篇
经济学   78篇
综合类   5篇
运输经济   1篇
旅游经济   1篇
贸易经济   27篇
农业经济   7篇
经济概况   18篇
  2023年   3篇
  2022年   1篇
  2021年   4篇
  2020年   8篇
  2019年   8篇
  2018年   5篇
  2017年   12篇
  2016年   11篇
  2015年   4篇
  2014年   11篇
  2013年   16篇
  2012年   6篇
  2011年   17篇
  2010年   13篇
  2009年   14篇
  2008年   18篇
  2007年   13篇
  2006年   11篇
  2005年   9篇
  2004年   4篇
  2003年   3篇
  2002年   3篇
  2001年   2篇
  2000年   2篇
  1999年   2篇
  1998年   1篇
  1994年   1篇
  1993年   1篇
  1992年   2篇
  1991年   2篇
  1990年   1篇
排序方式: 共有208条查询结果,搜索用时 46 毫秒
121.
This paper proposes a unified theoretical framework to discuss the costs and benefits of privatization using the recent advances of Incentive Theory. I begin by presenting a simple model in which the State (the principal) delegates a task (e.g., the production of a public good) to the private sector (the agent). I give and discuss conditions for the “Irrelevance Theorem” due to Sappington and Stiglitz [Sappington, D., & Stiglitz, J. (1987) Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 6, 567–582] to hold under complete contracting. I then show how various contract incompletenesses can make either public or private ownership optimal. Finally, I provide critical assessments of these results. I thank Patrick Rey and Wilfried Zantman for useful comments on an earlier draft. The excellent comments of two referees have also improved substantially the presentation and organization of the paper. I am deeply indebted to Denis Gromb for his extremely detailed comments.  相似文献   
122.
The objective of this paper is to present environmental policy as a simple game in two stages within a principal-agent framework. At the outset the authority adopts a transfer payment rule. Then the firms react by carrying out abatement activities, based on their chosen levels of emission and output. Next the authority measures the emissions (and residual profit of the industry) and revises the level of its instrument. Then the game starts again. Our purpose is to narrow the scope of ad hoc incentive schemes by characterizing families of optimal linear schemes.We thank two anonymous referees for their valuable suggestions. We have also benefited from comments from I.-M. Andréasson, J. B. Opschoor, H. Verbruggen and the other members of the Task Force II: Environmental Policy instruments of the European Science Foundation Programme: Environment, Science and Society. Wang acknowledges support from the Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft (DFG).  相似文献   
123.
银行高层激励:美国20家银行调查   总被引:25,自引:0,他引:25  
本文对 2 0 0 3年美国福布斯 50 0强排名中选出的 2 0家银行 1 992年至 2 0 0 2年的数据进行分析 ,研究包括董事局主席和CEO在内的高级管理人员的收入结构、收入时间序列变化 ,以及内部收入级差的特征 ,找出美国大银行高层报酬与激励中一些定量的、带有规律性的特点 ,对形成这些报酬特点的原因作初步探讨 ,作为中国银行业改革借鉴。  相似文献   
124.
要提高内地企业的激励性,就要突出公平,保持物资激励与非物资激励结合,组织目标和个人目标相结合,约束与激励结合。具体来说,内地企业需要扩大员工职业生涯发展空间,强化绩效考核的反馈面谈,严格实行合同化管理,实施全面薪酬战略,加强员工培训,注重内部晋升。  相似文献   
125.
Objectives:

To assess the views, knowledge, and experience of Dutch physicians with regard to the general objectives and values of the pay-for-performance (P4P) system, as the Dutch healthcare industry might find it useful, in terms of governance, to explore this approach further.

Methods:

A quantitative cross-sectional survey study was conducted among 48 physicians in surgical specialties in the Netherlands between May 2014 and July 2014. The survey questionnaire was designed to gather information regarding the intensity of feelings, on a 7-point Likert scale, toward statements that address the P4P system. Confidence intervals were calculated using the bootstrap technique with 1000 iterations.

Results:

Physicians see a positive value in P4P for their organizations rather than for personal attainment (mean?=?5.00; 95% CI?=?4.62–5.39), even though they feared that P4P might put financial pressure on them (mean?=?5.03; 95% CI?=?4.50–5.54). They strongly share the view that other colleagues will resist adopting P4P as a business model (mean?=?5.74; 95% CI?=?5.43–6.04). Respondents stated that they would not leave their current jobs if P4P were to be incorporated in their organization.

Conclusions:

Physicians see value in P4P for their organizations, and consider that P4P could provide an incentive for improving medical outcomes. There seems to be potential for the P4P system in the Netherlands as participants expressed positive support for its values. There is an intersection of interests between the value of P4P and the physicians’ aim of achieving quality outcomes; however, further studies would be needed to investigate perceptions about specific design features in a larger sample. In addition, prior to implementing P4P, broad education about the system should be provided in order to counteract pre-conceptions and prevent resistance.  相似文献   
126.
Recent theories of the multinational corporation introduce the property rights model of the firm and examine whether to integrate or outsource firm activities locally or to a foreign country. This paper focuses instead on the internal organization of the multinational corporation by examining the power allocation between headquarters and subsidiaries. We provide a framework to analyse the interaction between the decision to serve the local market by exporting or FDI, market access and the optimal mode of organization of the multinational corporation. We find that subsidiary managers are given decision power to run the firm at intermediate levels of host country competition. We then provide comparative statics on the optimal organization of the multinational corporation for changes in fixed FDI entry costs, trade costs, as well as changes in information technology.   相似文献   
127.
This paper reports on a series of experiments aimed at exploring in greater detail previous work on the effects of financial incentives on information use and task performance in a principal-agent setting. The paper also develops some new statistical modelling in the area of experimental testing including incorporation into the modelling approach of data from post-experiment questionnaires. We find significant support for the finding that profit-related individual money rewards encourage increased accessing of valuable but costly past profit information by agents – and that this in turn enhances individual performance in earning profit for the agency.  相似文献   
128.
A regulatory approved deed of cross guarantee (the deed) was introduced into Australia in December 1991, relieving participating companies within a group from having to prepare, have audited, and file financial statements. We examine the characteristics of firms that obtain relief from filing (and therefore disclosing) separate financial statements of closed‐group companies by adopting the deed. This is the first attempt to analyse adoption using large‐scale archival data. The results support the survey evidence in Dean and Clarke (2005 ), thus providing triangulation on their work. In particular they support the view that the decision to adopt the deed is a function of strategic factors as well as accounting and auditing cost savings. Those strategic factors were not in focus when regulators first introduced a deed of indemnity in 1985, nor when the original indemnity was modified to become a deed of cross guarantee in 1991 or when it was further modified in 1998. Further, evidence is provided to test the conflicting ideas arising from the analytical literature and the mixed results in the empirical, voluntary disclosure literatures. That evidence suggests that non‐disclosure arises when firms are in a more competitive industry and, in particular, when there is ability to retain non‐disclosure at the consolidated level (i.e., where the number of segments is high). Other factors supporting non‐disclosure are leverage and the proportion of foreign operations (proxying for deed complexity). The proportion of outside directors (a proxy for legal liability) and the number of shares outstanding (a proxy for agency costs of equity) are not associated with the decision to adopt the deed.  相似文献   
129.
段姝  杨彬 《科技进步与对策》2020,37(16):120-127
在“大众创新万众创业”的时代背景下,激发微观主体创新活力具有重要战略意义。政府补贴是提升企业创新强度的一项重要政策工具,主要形式有财政补贴和税收优惠。选取2013-2017年在我国中小板上市的民营科技型企业为研究样本,采用固定效应模型,实证分析财政补贴和税收优惠对企业研发创新强度的影响效应,进一步考察企业规模特征对两种政府补贴工具效应的影响,并引入企业生命周期模型,考察政府补贴在民营科技型企业创新活动中的最佳投入阶段。研究结果表明:财政补贴对研发创新强度影响不显著,税收优惠能显著提升创新强度;企业规模在政府补贴与企业创新强度间存在显著调节作用,企业规模越大,政府补贴对企业创新强度的激励效应越弱。通过采用纳入企业生命周期因素的模型进行分析发现:政府补贴对成长期和成熟期民营科技型企业创新强度具有显著激励作用,对初创期和衰退期民营科技型企业创新强度影响不显著。  相似文献   
130.
School choice reforms give talented students the option to sort out of low-performing schools but often leave disadvantaged students behind. This study shows how a Chinese city was successful in helping its low-performing schools to catch up by encouraging talented students to sort into these schools. The city identified eleven low-performing middle schools and guaranteed elite high school admission to their top ten-percent graduates. This study documents that the policy improved school performance by 0.19-0.26 standard deviations. Using data on lottery middle school assignment, I further test for potential mechanisms, including strategic sorting and improvement in school value-added.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号