首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
相似文献
 共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 437 毫秒
1.
作为一种新生力量和经济形态,循环经济在我国起步较晚,其发展还面临许多主、客观约束,如:政府、公众和企业三大循环经济主体对片面经济利益的追求;旧体制路径依赖机制的制约;不完善的法律法规体系;不够深入的循环经济理论研究;等等。  相似文献   

2.
《经济师》2016,(4)
现阶段,国家在资源利用方面的要求越来越高,循环经济发展模式也应运而生。其目的在于降低污染排放,提高环境与资源利用率,从根本上协调经济与自然资源之间的关系。作为发展循环经济的主体,中小企业的发展受到了多方面因素的制约,例如技术落后、企业布局不集中、市场失灵以及成本问题等。文章通过SWOT的分析方法对黑龙江中小企业循环经济发展现状及其制约因素进行分析,对其支撑体系提出相应的原则与内容构建建议。  相似文献   

3.
我国企业发展循环经济的制约因素分析与对策研究   总被引:2,自引:0,他引:2  
企业是发展循环经济的主体,在一国发展循环经济和保持经济社会的可持续发展过程中发挥着重要的作用。文章从我国企业自身条件、市场机制和政府调控手段三个方面分析了企业发展循环经济的制约因素,提出了推动企业发展循环经济的相应对策。  相似文献   

4.
企业是发展循环经济的主体,企业发展循环经济不仅是时代所需,环境所迫,而且是企业自身持续发展的必然选择。本文重点分析了企业在发展循环经济中的层次性以及企业在实践过程中的策略性问题。  相似文献   

5.
企业既是技术创新的主要力量,也是新技术最大的直接收益者,这就决定了企业在构建循环经济技术支撑体系中的主体地住。企业作为社会的创新主体必须转变发展理念和创新思维,积极围绕循环经济的“减量化(reduce)”、“再使用(reuse)”、“再循环(recycle)原则”,构建新的技术平台,实现企业的可持续发展。  相似文献   

6.
随着可持续发展战略的提出和广泛应用,越来越多的企业开始关注循环经济,并将其作为实现环境与经济协调发展的重要手段。循环经济在一定程度上促进了企业发展,然而其在发展中常因人力资源管理制度的不完善,而使循环经济不能更好的推动企业发展。在这种情况下,有必要制定出与之相适应的循环经济人力资源管理策略。本文主要从循环经济概念、企业人力资源管理战略两方面出发,对基于循环经济的企业人力资源管理战略进行探析。  相似文献   

7.
根据我国所处的发展阶段、资源情况和战略目标,发展循环经济是必要的,也是必然的,但是对于发展循环经济的主体——企业而言,则不能仅从资源环境的角度要求其考虑经济活动的社会后果,还必须从实施效率的角度进行成本-收益分析,达到发展循环经济的同时实现各企业经济的正常循环。基于这个角度分析认为,经济系统内的物质循环、价值循环与信息循环的耦合,是实现循环经济系统内经济循环的必要条件,同时也是构筑企业发展循环经济的内在动力机制。  相似文献   

8.
20世纪90年代之后,发展循环经济成为国际社会的趋势.发达国家以发展循环经济作为实施可持续发展战略的重要途径和实现方式.循环经济对发达国家企业的发展产生了积极的影响,企业在政府的支持下,将发展循环经济纳入其长期发展战略,不仅为宏观循环经济发展注入了力量,同时也大大增强了企业的竞争力.  相似文献   

9.
循环经济是科学发展观指导下的新经济发展模式,从资源循环利用、企业清洁生产到目前的生态企业、生态产业园区、社会循环经济系统等理论和实践模式,已成为"科学发展"和新型工业化的主要发展模式。国家推进循环经济试点企业和城市对区域持续发展具有重大意义,石河子市和天业集团作为国家循环经济的试点,其发展模式和取得的成绩与经验对区域循环经济发展有一定的理论和实践价值。  相似文献   

10.
中小企业发展循环经济的动力机制研究   总被引:5,自引:0,他引:5  
汪上 《技术经济》2006,25(2):9-11
中小企业作为我国经济发展的重要主体,应该主动承担起发展循环经济的任务。本文从政府推动、企业实现规模经济的内在要求、政府的环境保护政策及社会可持续发展需要、社会资源约束、绿色理念的广泛树立五个方面分析了我国中小企业发展循环经济的动力机制,提出了建立循环经济法律体系、加强政府监督力度、加强中小企业市场经济伦理建设等发展循环经济的措施。  相似文献   

11.
Abstract

The purpose of this paper is to introduce explicitly pleasure and belief in what aims at being a Humean theory of decision, like the one developed in Diaye and Lapidus (2005a). Although we support the idea that Hume was in some way a hedonist – evidently different from Bentham's or Jevons' way – we lay emphasis less on continuity than on the specific kind of hedonism encountered in Hume's writings (chiefly the Treatise, the second Enquiry, the Dissertation, or some of his Essays). Such hedonism clearly contrasts to its standard modern inheritance, expressed by the relation between preferences and utility.

The reason for such a difference with the usual approach lies in the mental process that Hume puts to the fore in order to explain the way pleasure determines desires and volition. Whereas pleasure is primarily, in Hume's words, an impression of sensation, it takes place in the birth of passions as reflecting an idea of pleasure, whose “force and vivacity” is precisely a “belief”, transferred to the direct passions of desire or volition that come immediately before action. As a result, from a Humean point of view, “belief” deals with decision under risk or uncertainty, as well as with intertemporal decision and indiscrimination problems.

The latter are explored within a formal framework, and it is shown that the relation of pleasure is transformed by belief into a non-empty class of relations of desire, among which at least one is a preorder.  相似文献   

12.
Neoliberal political movements advocate privatization of public pension systems. Globalization imposes pressure on nations to conform to neoliberal policy views with respect to the design and structure of social insurance, including public pension systems. The paper begins with an investigation of the economic, ethical and ideological dimensions of the privatization debates in the U.S.; it argues that privatization advocates may be largely moved by ideology, since the other reasons advanced appear weak or unfounded. The second part discusses the history of Social Security, the purposes for its creation, and some of its economic effects. Differences between public and private pension systems are considered. A brief international comparison of some aspects of public pension system finance and benefit structures is presented. The final section considers the ethical, macroeconomic and distributional implications of privatization, prefunding and payroll tax funding, and argues for a pay as you go system financed with income taxes. In order to promote equity, economic security, community, and social cohesion, public pension systems should be universal in coverage. In order to reduce the inequality, income insecurity, and aged poverty generated by market economies, public pension systems ought to be progressive: benefit/contribution ratios should be inversely proportional to income, and progressive income taxes should finance the system. To promote economic growth, the systems should be financed on a pay-as-you-go basis, and should not be prefunded except for an emergency reserve. The fiscal policy recommendations partially depend upon the theory developed by Abba Lerner in the 1940s, and recently advanced by Wynne Godley and Randy Wray: Lerner's “principle of functional finance.”  相似文献   

13.
This article seeks to evaluate the appropriateness of a variety of existing forecasting techniques (17 methods) at providing accurate and statistically significant forecasts for gold price. We report the results from the nine most competitive techniques. Special consideration is given to the ability of these techniques to provide forecasts which outperforms the random walk (RW) as we noticed that certain multivariate models (which included prices of silver, platinum, palladium and rhodium, besides gold) were also unable to outperform the RW in this case. Interestingly, the results show that none of the forecasting techniques are able to outperform the RW at horizons of 1 and 9 steps ahead, and on average, the exponential smoothing model is seen providing the best forecasts in terms of the lowest root mean squared error over the 24-month forecasting horizons. Moreover, we find that the univariate models used in this article are able to outperform the Bayesian autoregression and Bayesian vector autoregressive models, with exponential smoothing reporting statistically significant results in comparison with the former models, and classical autoregressive and the vector autoregressive models in most cases.  相似文献   

14.
In principle, we want regulatory programs to be based on current realities, as reflected for example in the best knowledge of relevant experts. That would imply that old rules now on the books should be consistent with today's knowledge base, not just what was known when a rule or standard was originally set. This paper reports on a survey of US programs, examining how often existing rules are actually updated in light of better knowledge, and identifies five programs that attempt to make policy routinely adaptive. These programs exhibit what we term Planned Adaptation: they both revise rules when relevant new knowledge appears, and take steps to produce such improved knowledge. While Planned Adaptation is rare, it is used in several nationally prominent programs, including air pollution, airplane safety, and drug safety. Planned Adaptation is a policy tool that deserves more attention.  相似文献   

15.
The payment of interest on reserves has been a common practice in inflationary economies. This policy may seem paradoxical since it involves returning part of the seigniorage, generated by the inflation process, with the intention to finance the fiscal deficit. This paper argues that the motivation for this policy can be captured by the discretionary regime, where the policymaker pays interest on reserves because he is concerned with the erosion of real liquidity by inflation, which is in part beyond his control. However, this policy is an unlikely outcome in the commitment regime, where the policymaker is in full control of inflation.  相似文献   

16.
The buildup of so-called greenhouse gases in the atmosphere — CO2 in particular-appears to be having an adverse impact on the global climate. This paper briefly reviews current expectations with regard to physical and biological effects, their potential costs to society, and likely costs of abatement. For a worst case scenario it is impossible to assess, in economic terms, the full range of possible non-linear synergistic effects. In the most favorable (although not necessarily likely) case (of slow-paced climate change), however, it seems likely that the impacts are within the affordable range, at least in the industrialized countries of the world. In the third world the notion of affordability is of doubtful relevance, making the problem of quantitative evaluation almost impossible. We tentatively assess the lower limit of quantifiable climate-induced damages at $30 to $35 per ton of CO2 equivalent, worldwide, with the major damages being concentrated in regions most adversely affected by sea-level rise. The non-quantifiable environmental damages are also significant and should by no means be disregarded.The costs and benefits of (1) reducing CFC use and (2) reducing fossil fuel consumption, as a means of abatement, are considered in some detail. This strategy has remarkably high indirect benefits in terms of reduced air pollution damage and even direct cost savings to consumers. The indirect benefits of reduced air pollution and its associated health and environmental effects from fossil-fuel combustion in the industrialized countries range from $20 to $60 per ton of CO2 eliminated. In addition, there is good evidence that modest (e.g. 25%) reductions in CO2 emissions may be achievable by the U.S. (and, by implication, for other countries) by a combination of increased energy efficiency and restructuring that would permit simultaneous direct economic benefits (savings) to energy consumers of the order of $50 per ton of CO2 saved. A higher level of overall emissions reduction — possibly approaching 50% — could probably be achieved, at little or not net cost, by taking advantage of these savings.We suggest the use of taxes on fossil fuel extraction (or a carbon tax) as a reasonable way of inducing the structural changes that would be required to achieve significant reduction in energy use and CO2 emissions. To minimize the economic burden (and create a political constituency in support of the approach) we suggest the substitution of resource-based taxes in general for other types of taxes (on labor, income, real estate, or trade) that are now the main sources of government revenue. While it is conceded that it would be difficult to calculate the optimal tax on extractive resources, we do not think this is a necessary prerequisite to policy-making. In fact, we note that the existing tax system has never been optimized according to theoretical principles, and is far from optimal by any reasonable criteria.During the academic year 1989–90 Dr. Ayres was at the International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis (IIASA), Laxenburg, Austria.During the summer of 1989 Mr. Walter was a member of the Young Scientists' Summer Program at IIASA.  相似文献   

17.
This paper describes flows of basic research through the US economy during the late 20th century. In addition, the paper studies the effect of the flows on scientific papers in industries and fields. This article differs from others in its use of measures of science rather than technology. Together, its results present a picture of the structure of basic research flows in a modern, science-intensive economy. Basic research flows are large within petrochemicals and drugs, and within software and communications. Flows of chemistry, physics, and engineering are common throughout all industries – biology and medicine are almost confined to petrochemicals and drugs; and computer science is nearly as restricted to software and communications. In general, basic research flows are more concentrated within scientific fields than within industries. Our findings concerning the production of scientific papers indicate that the effect of a 1% change in academic R&D spillovers significantly exceeds that of industrial spillovers. In addition, within-field effects exceed effects between-fields, while within- and between-industry effects are roughly equal. It follows that scientific fields limit basic research flows more than industries do, perhaps because large firms implicitly span a range of industries.  相似文献   

18.
The multiperiod probit model is presented and Bayesian estimation using the Gibbs sampler with data augmentation is described. As an empirical illustration, the multiperiod probit model is then used to estimate a duration model using employment duration data for the Canadian province of New Brunswick. Bayesian estimation with unobserved heterogeneity is shown to be a simple extension of estimation of a duration model with no unobserved heterogeneity. More importantly, perhaps, some numerical problems encountered by other authors using Maximum Likelihood are avoided.I would like to thank M. Baker, G. Koop, A. Melino and D. Poirier for helpful comments and discussions. I would also like to thank M. Baker for providing his data.  相似文献   

19.
To be creative and make change happen, leaders must do more than simply ‘think outside the box’, as the traditional business manuals suggest, using the popular American expression. After all, the space outside the box is infinitely expansive. Moreover, there can be no guarantee that a solution to the problem will be found. The answer: ‘Think in new boxes.’ This requires developing the right new box; in other words, useful new models, a helpful new approach to a problem. That is the real art of practical creativity. This short article outlines the approach (Thinking in New Boxes) and its application to classic scenario planning with a few examples. The authors also present the ‘Expressway to Scenarios’, an approach that wins in impact and practicality what it loses in deep analysis, by having top executives involved in key steps.  相似文献   

20.
Any adequate analysis of economic globalization necessarily requires fundamental understanding of the worldviews underlying the views expressed with respect to the nature and role of economic globalization. This paper is based on the premise that any worldview can be associated with one of the four basic paradigms: functionalist, interpretive, radical humanist, and radical structuralist. It argues that any view expressed with respect to economic globalization is based on one of the four paradigms or worldviews. It, therefore, discusses four views with respect to the nature and role of economic globalization which correspond to the four broad worldviews. The paper emphasizes that the four views expressed are equally scientific and informative; they look at the nature and role of economic globalization from a certain paradigmatic viewpoint. Emphasizing this example in the area of economic globalization, the paper concludes that there are opportunities for each paradigm to benefit from contributions coming from the other three paradigms.  相似文献   

设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号