首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   807篇
  免费   15篇
财政金融   88篇
工业经济   29篇
计划管理   121篇
经济学   308篇
综合类   43篇
运输经济   18篇
旅游经济   4篇
贸易经济   90篇
农业经济   30篇
经济概况   91篇
  2024年   1篇
  2023年   10篇
  2022年   14篇
  2021年   30篇
  2020年   44篇
  2019年   26篇
  2018年   19篇
  2017年   37篇
  2016年   33篇
  2015年   25篇
  2014年   49篇
  2013年   54篇
  2012年   40篇
  2011年   73篇
  2010年   33篇
  2009年   49篇
  2008年   59篇
  2007年   64篇
  2006年   43篇
  2005年   30篇
  2004年   19篇
  2003年   21篇
  2002年   8篇
  2001年   13篇
  2000年   7篇
  1999年   4篇
  1998年   3篇
  1997年   3篇
  1996年   3篇
  1995年   3篇
  1994年   1篇
  1993年   2篇
  1992年   2篇
排序方式: 共有822条查询结果,搜索用时 62 毫秒
1.
企业创新是国家经济可持续增长的关键,受到管理层意愿的影响,因而需要对内部经营者的权力进行制衡。以2010-2018年我国A股上市公司为研究样本,实证检验管理层权力制衡强度对企业创新投资的影响,以及不同债务约束情境下高商业信用配置、高负债水平的调节效应,此外,还考察了产权性质的差异化影响。研究表明,管理层权力制衡强度越大,企业创新投资水平越高;高商业信用强化了该促进作用,而高负债水平弱化了该促进作用。进一步研究发现,管理层权力制衡强度与企业创新投资的关系在民企中更显著;国企能够更好地获得和运用商业信用,使其高商业信用对该关系的强化效应更显著;民企具有更强的债务约束,其高负债水平对该关系的弱化效应更明显。  相似文献   
2.
以277家中小板和创业板上市公司2012-2017年平衡面板数据为样本,利用泊松模型,实证分析知识型员工冗余与企业二元创新的关系,并探讨外部环境特征(要素市场发育程度和市场不确定性)的调节机理。研究表明:企业应保持一定的知识型员工冗余,促进企业二元式创新,过多或过少的知识型员工冗余均不利于企业开展创新活动;不同的环境特征对二者间关系的调节作用存在异质性,要素市场发育程度会减弱知识型员工冗余与探索式创新、利用式创新间关系,而市场不确定性会加强知识型员工冗余与探索式创新、利用式创新间关系。  相似文献   
3.
基于价值链视角,构建涵盖人才资源在区域空间层面集聚生成、地区配置、效能产出3个维度在内的区域人才集聚水平评价指标体系,采用专家咨询AHP-信息熵组合赋权法构建综合评价模型和耦合协调度模型,对2010—2018年长江经济带沿线省市人才集聚水平进行测度与时空演化特征分析。结果表明,就长江经济带整体而言,考察期内地区人才集聚水平总体呈现逐年上升态势,但仍处于低水平状态;沿线省市人才集聚水平差异显著,缩小趋势渐缓,整体呈现局部高水平、全局低效率的不利境况;各省市人才集聚水平关键维度的耦合协调度整体呈显著波动递增态势,但内部耦合协调度存在不平衡发展问题,影响地区人才集聚水平整体提升。为提升长江经济带人才集聚水平,推进沿线地区协调发展,需强化区域人才合作机制,采取差别化精准策略破解沿线地区人才集聚低水平、不协调的短板因素。  相似文献   
4.
李政  杨思莹 《南方经济》2019,38(12):49-67
文章基于2003年至2016年我国215个城市面板数据,运用双重差分模型、空间双重差分模型和分位数回归模型等方法,实证检验了国家高新区对城市创新水平的影响及其空间异质性特征。研究结果表明,国家高新区建设显著提升了城市创新水平,并且高新区设立带动的城市投资集聚是推动城市创新水平提升的重要原因。空间双重差分结果表明,国家高新区对城市创新水平的提升作用并非源于其对周边城市创新资源的掠夺,相反高新区设立对周边城市和省内城市均产生了显著的溢出效应,提升了本省城市和周边外省城市创新水平。此外,国家高新区对城市创新水平的影响具有空间异质性特征,在省会城市、直辖市和副省级城市,高新区对城市创新水平的影响并不显著,而能够显著提升一般地级市创新水平;随着城市创新水平的提升,高新区建设对城市创新水平的促进作用呈现出先增强、后减弱直至不再显著的非对称"倒V型"变化特征。但是研究也发现,国家高新区对城市创新水平影响的区位异质性并不显著,高新区对东部地区和中西部地区城市创新水平提升均具有显著的促进作用。  相似文献   
5.
Welfare in economics is generally conceived of in terms of the satisfaction of preferences, but a general, comparable index measure of welfare is generally not taken to be possible. In recent years, in response to the usage of measures of subjective well-being as indices of welfare in economics, a number of economists have started to develop measures of welfare based on preference-satisfaction. In order to evaluate the success of such measures, I formulate criteria of policy-relevance and theoretical success in the context of preference-satisfaction measures of welfare. I present a detailed case study of the methodological choices put forward in a prominent generalized proposal for measuring welfare through preferences recently published in the American Economic Review. I contrast this with an alternative welfare measure which also uses preferences to weight aspects of welfare: the ICECAP-A measure. I assess the methodology of both approaches in detail and argue that the two goals of a preference measure of welfare can only be satisfied at the expense of making a measure prohibitively costly.  相似文献   
6.
The impact of uncertainty on consumption and welfare seems obvious; because of the precautionary saving motive, higher uncertainty reduces consumption, and subsequently, deteriorates welfare. Recent several studies, however, find that this intuitive narrative is not necessarily true. This paper provides the analytical underpinnings for this. In the absence of technological progress, I find that the larger demographic shocks always reduce consumption, but improve the welfare of households. Moreover, when demographic shocks are negatively tied to technology shocks, there emerges an inverted-U relationship between the size of two shocks and consumption, and a U-shaped relationship between the size of two shocks and household welfare. These results are all characterized analytically in the framework of the stochastic two-sector growth model featuring the correlated Brownian motion process. The findings suggest that demographic policies should not be implemented with no reference to the state of technology.  相似文献   
7.
开放式创新行为对提高企业创新绩效有显著影响。基于2012年世界银行调查数据,对中国企业开放式创新行为影响因素进行了实证分析。研究表明:①企业开放式创新行为在区域、行业上分布不均;②竞争对手情况、信息技术支持度、数据软件共享度、产品出口、产品销售范围等对研发合作有显著正向影响;③高管工作经历、竞争者数量、信息技术支持度等对企业创新开放度有显著正向影响。  相似文献   
8.
Agricultural commodity markets in developing countries often operate in a constrained environment of prohibitive transaction costs. Consequently, smallholder farmers are only partly integrated into these markets, a situation that keeps them in a lower level of development equilibrium (poverty trap). Although cooperative institutional alternatives such as Farmers’ Organizations (FOs) may reduce transaction costs and revitalize agricultural production and commercialization, they rarely have been successful in fully delivering on these promises. Against this backdrop, the World Food Programmed (WFP) has recently implemented a multi-year and multi-country pilot to increase smallholder participation in commodity markets. The projects involved investing in physical and human capacities of Farmer Organizations (FOs) to aggregate commodities and add value, as well as locally purchasing food aid from the same. The combination of interventions was expected to increase the relative price of agricultural products, particularly staple crops. In this study, using Ethiopian panel survey data, we estimated the causal income and investment effects of the Ethiopian P4P intervention among smallholders. Using an entropy balancing (EB) model and semi-parametric difference-in-difference (DID) model, we show that the P4P intervention has increased per capita consumption by smallholders. Our additional analysis confirms that this effect is heterogeneous owing to elite capture within Farmer Organizations. We also find evidence of increased food consumption scores, increased investments in child schooling, and increased asset holding among program-participating smallholders relative to comparison farmers. Policy implications are discussed.  相似文献   
9.
Do people “vote with their feet” in response to a lack of political competition? Since political competition is associated with higher growth and welfare, with the free movement of labour, we argue that it should also encourage inward migration. We test this hypothesis by using data from the US and find a strong positive relation between political competition and net migration. This result is robust to alternative specifications, alternative samples and addressing endogeneity using the Voting Rights Act to instrument for political competition. The effect is economically large, specifically, we find that an increase in political competition in the order of magnitude observed in US Southern states during the post-war period leads to an increase in net migration by between 27 and 44 individuals per 1000 population.  相似文献   
10.
This paper extends Melitz and Redding (2015) to analyze the welfare gains from trade liberalization by adding foreign direct investment(FDI). Our model predicts that with FDI activities, welfare gains from trade liberalization will be strictly lower than those in a model without FDI, but only takes exports into account. In addition, the calibrated model indicates that with FDI activities, aggregate welfare reaches its maximum when the fixed export costs are positive rather than 0. Furthermore, we decompose the welfare gains induced by trade liberalization from continuing exporters, and switchers. The results show that in any case, with or without FDI, continuing exporters contribute a larger share to welfare gains than status switching firms.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号